- Research
- Open Access
- Published:
Fully coupled forward-backward stochastic differential equations on Markov chains
Advances in Difference Equations volume 2016, Article number: 133 (2016)
Abstract
We define fully coupled forward-backward stochastic differential equations on spaces related to continuous-time finite-state Markov chains. Existence and uniqueness results of the fully coupled forward-backward stochastic differential equations on Markov chains are obtained.
1 Introduction
Since the first introduction by Pardoux and Peng [1] in 1990, the theory of nonlinear backward stochastic differential equations (BSDEs) driven by a Brownian motion has been intensively researched by many researchers and has achieved abundant theoretical results. Now this theory is a powerful tool in stochastic analysis. It also has many important applications, namely in stochastic control, stochastic differential games, finance, and the theory of partial differential equations (PDEs).
In the classic BSDE theory, we consider a Brownian motion as the driver, but a Brownian motion is a kind of very idealized stochastic model, which limits greatly the applications of the classic BSDEs. There are many results about BSDEs associated with jump process. Tang and Li [2] first discussed BSDEs driven by a Brownian motion and Poisson process; Nualart and Schoutens [3] considered BSDEs driven by a Brownian motion and Lévy process. Furthermore, there are also results where the Brownian motion in the diffusion term of the BSDE is replaced by another process. For example, Cohen and Elliott [4] studied BSDEs driven by a continuous-time finite-state Markov chain. After that, many results, such as a comparison theorem about this kind of BSDEs, nonlinear expected results [5, 6], and so on, appeared.
Along with the rapid development of the BSDE theory, the theory of fully coupled forward-backward stochastic differential equations (FBSDEs), closely related to BSDEs, has been developed rapidly. Fully coupled FBSDEs with Brownian motion can be encountered in the optimization problem when applying stochastic maximum principle (see [7]) and in mathematical finance when considering a large investor in security market (see [8]). Such FBSDEs are also used in the potential theory (see [9]). As we know now, to get the existence and uniqueness results of fully coupled FBSDEs solutions, there are mainly three methods: the method of contraction mappings [10, 11], the four-step scheme [12], and the method of continuation [13, 14]. For more details on fully coupled FBSDEs, we refer to Yong [15], Ma et al. [16], or Briand and Hu [17] and the references therein.
In this paper, we study fully coupled FBSDEs driven by a martingale generated by a continuous-time finite-state Markov chain. Inspired by Peng and Wu [14], we introduce an \(m\times n\) full-rank matrix G to overcome the problem caused by the different dimensions of SDE and BSDE. Using the method of continuation, the Itô product rule of semimartingales, and the fixed point principle, based on the theory of BSDEs driven by a continuous-time finite-state Markov chain, we obtain existence and uniqueness results of the FBSDEs on a Markov chain. It is worth pointing out that due to the property of the martingale generated by a finite-state Markov chain, the form of the monotone assumptions we employed here is different from that in Peng and Wu [14].
Recently, many works have been done on BSDEs with Markov chains. In fact, there are two major formulations of the state space of the Markov chain in the literature. One is the set of unit vectors in some Euclidean space [18]. The other one is the set of positive integers [19]. Each of the formulations was used by many researchers when they studied BSDEs driven by Markov chains. When a martingale representation was needed, the second formulation was necessary. The first one facilitates the mathematics, that is, the symbolism is nicer; the second one makes the mathematics more rigorous. Given a continuous-time Markov chain, assuming its state space be the set of positive integers, there exists an integer-valued random measure that counts the jumps of a Markov chain. Crepey and Matoussi [19] and Crepey [20] considered BSDEs driven by both a Brownian motion and the compensated martingale of a random measure. Tao et al. [21] discussed BSDEs with a singular perturbed Markov chain; Tao et al. [22, 23] considered the regime-switching system modulated by a Markov chain based on Crepey and Matoussi [19] and Crepey [20]. When the state space of a continuous-time Markov chain is described by the set of unit vectors in \(R^{d}\), Zhang et al. [18] considered a system of Markov regime-switching model with Poisson jumps. Different from the above works, based on Cohen and Elliott [4], we discussed FBSDEs purely driven by a Markov chain rather than by a Brownian motion. Our model depends only on the state space of a Markov chain and leads to a special structure.
In Section 2, we formulate our problem; in Section 3, the preliminaries are given; in Section 4, we give our main result on the existence and uniqueness of the fully coupled FBSDE on a Markov chain and present the proofs; in Section 5, we discuss the existence and uniqueness result of the FBSDE under other monotone assumptions; in the last section, we give an application of these theoretical results to stochastic optimal control problem through an example.
2 Formulation of the problem
Consider a continuous-time finite-state Markov chain \(m=\{m_{t},t\in [0,T]\}\). Following the convention of Elliott et al. [24], we assume that it takes values in unit vectors \(e_{i}\) in \(R^{d}\), where d is the number of states of the chain.
We consider stochastic processes defined on the filtered probability space \((\Omega,\mathscr{F},\mathscr{F}_{t},\mathbb{P})\), where \(\{\mathscr{F}_{t}\}\) is the completed natural filtration generated by the σ-fields \(\mathscr{F}_{t}=\sigma(\{m_{s}, s\leq t \},F\in\mathscr{F}_{T}:\mathbb{P}(F)=0)\), and \(\mathscr{F}=\mathscr{F}_{T}\). Note that if m is right-continuous, then this filtration is right-continuous. If \(\mathcal{A}_{t}\) denotes the rate matrix for m at time t, then this chain has the following representation:
where \(M_{t}\) is a martingale (see [24]).
We consider the following forward-backward stochastic differential equations:
where X, Y, Z take values in \(\mathbb{R}^{n}\), \(\mathbb{R}^{m}\), \(\mathbb{R}^{m\times d}\), \(T>0\) is an arbitrary fixed number, and b, σ, f, Φ are functions of appropriate dimensions:
We shall seek an \(\mathscr{F}_{t}\)-adapted triple \((X,Y,Z)\) that satisfies the forward-backward stochastic differential equation (1) on \([0,T]\) \(\mathbb{P}\)-almost surely. That is, our aim is to find an \(\mathscr{F}_{t}\)-adapted solution of (1).
Noting that only the s-left limit \(\sigma(\omega, s-,X_{s-},Y_{s-},Z_{s-})\) enters into FBSDE (1), without loss of generality, we assume that \(\sigma (s,X_{s},Y_{s},Z_{s})\) is left-continuous in s for all w and X, Y. Since M is a semimartingale, X, Y is cà dlà g and adapted. We suppose the existence of the left limits of Z. So Z must have at most a countable number of discontinuities, and then it must be left-continuous at each t except possibly on a dt-null set. Hence, if \(Z_{s}\) satisfies FBSDE (1), then so does \(Z_{s-}\):
Setting \(Z_{t}^{**}:=Z_{t-}\), we have a left-continuous process \(Z^{**}\), which also satisfies the desired equations. Therefore, writing the left limits \(Z_{t-}\) is unnecessary since we simply assume that our solution is left-continuous.
Based on these arguments, we rewrite FBSDE (1) as
Recall that FBSDE (1) is equivalent to
where \(b^{**}(s,X_{s},Y_{s},Z_{s})=b(s,X_{s},Y_{s},Z_{s})-\sigma (s,X_{s},Y_{s},Z_{s})\mathcal {A}_{s}m_{s}\) and \(f^{**}(s,X_{s},Y_{s},Z_{s})=f(s,X_{s}, Y_{s},Z_{s})+Z_{s}\mathcal {A}_{s}m_{s}\).
Obviously, FBSDE (2) is driven by the Markov chain \(m=\{ m_{t},t\in[0,T]\}\).
3 Preliminaries
3.1 Preliminary notation
Elliott et al. [24] obtained the optional quadratic variation of \(M_{t}\) as the matrix process
where ‘∗’ means transpose.
Observing that \(\mathcal{A}\) is the rate matrix of the Markov chain m, the predictable quadratic variation is
This can be seen through considering
and
Equating these two, we get
where L is some martingale. This in turn suggests that
We will use the following notation:
By \((\cdot,\cdot)\) we denote the usual inner product in \(\mathbb{R}^{n}\) or \(\mathbb{R}^{m}\); we use the usual Euclidean norm in \(\mathbb{R}^{n}\) and \(\mathbb{R}^{m}\); and for \(z\in\mathbb {R}^{m\times d}\), we define \(|z|=\{\operatorname{tr}(zz^{*})\}^{\frac{1}{2}}\).
For \(z^{1}\in\mathbb{R}^{m\times d}\), \(z^{2}\in\mathbb{R}^{m\times d}\),
and for \(u^{1}=(x^{1},y^{1},z^{1})\in\mathbb{R}^{n}\times\mathbb {R}^{m}\times\mathbb{R}^{m\times d} \), \(u^{2}=(x^{2},y^{2},z^{2})\in\mathbb{R}^{n}\times\mathbb {R}^{m}\times\mathbb{R}^{m\times d} \),
We are given an \(m\times n\) full-rank matrix G. For \(u=(x,y,z)\in\mathbb{R}^{n}\times\mathbb{R}^{m}\times \mathbb{R}^{m\times d}\), let
where \(G\sigma=(G\sigma_{1} \cdots G\sigma_{d})\).
Furthermore, we define
where v is a basis vector in \(\mathbb{R}^{d}\).
3.2 BSDEs on Markov chains
We recall the existence and uniqueness results for a solution to the following BSDE on a Markov chain:
for functions \(F_{1}:\Omega\times[0,T]\times\mathbb{R}^{n}\times \mathbb{R}^{n \times d}\) and \(F_{2}:\Omega\times[0,T]\times \mathbb{R}^{n}\); these functions are assumed to be progressively measurable, that is, \(F_{1}(\cdot,s,Y_{s},Z_{s})\) and \(F_{2}(\cdot,s,Y_{s})\) are \(\mathscr{F}_{t}\)-measurable for all \(t\in[0,T] \).
Cohen and Elliott [4] gave the following result about martingale representation.
Lemma 1
Any \(R^{d}\)-valued martingale L defined on \((\Omega,\mathscr{F}_{t},\mathbb{P})\) can be represented as a stochastic (in this case, Stieltjes) integral with respect to the martingale process M up to equality \(\mathbb{P}\)-a.s. This representation is unique up to a \(d\langle M,M \rangle_{t}\times \mathbb{P}\)-null set. That is,
where \(Z_{s}\) is a predictable \(\mathbb{R}^{n\times d}\)-valued matrix process.
Cohen and Elliott [4] also obtained the existence and uniqueness of a solution to the above BSDE.
Theorem 1
Assume the Lipschitz continuity on the generators \(F_{2}\) and \(F_{2}\), that is, that there exists \(c\in\mathbb{R}\) such that, for all \(s\in[0,T]\),
Under this Lipschitz condition, the above equation has at most one solution up to indistinguishability for Y and equality \(d\langle M,M\rangle_{t}\times\mathbb{P}\)-a.s. for Y.
4 Existence and uniqueness for FBSDE (1)
We give two definitions.
Definition 1
We denote by \(\mathcal {M}^{2}(0,T;\mathbb{R}^{n})\) the set of all \({R}^{n}\)-valued \(\mathscr{F}_{t}\)-adapted processes such that
Definition 2
A triple of processes \((X,Y,Z): \Omega\times [0,T] \rightarrow\mathbb{R}^{n}\times\mathbb{R}^{m}\times \mathbb{R}^{m\times d}\) is called an adapted solution of the FBSDE (1) if \((X,Y,Z)\in\mathcal {M}^{2}(0,T;\mathbb{R}^{n}\times\mathbb{R}^{m}\times \mathbb{R}^{m\times d})\) and it satisfies FBSDE (1) \(\mathbb{P}\)-almost surely.
The adaptedness of the solution enables us to rewrite FBSDE (1) in a differential form:
Now we give the main assumptions of our paper.
Assumption 1
For each \(u=(x,y,z)\in\mathbb{R}^{n}\times \mathbb{R}^{m}\times\mathbb{R}^{m\times d}\), \(F(\cdot,u), H(\cdot ,u)\in\mathcal{M}^{2}(0,T;\mathbb{R}^{n}\times\mathbb{R}^{m}\times \mathbb{R}^{m\times d})\), and for each \(x\in\mathbb{R}^{n}\), \(\Phi(x)\in L^{2}(\Omega,\mathscr{F}_{T};\mathbb{R}^{n})\). Moreover,
-
(i)
\(F(t,u)\) is uniformly Lipschitz with respect to u;
-
(ii)
\(H(t,u)\) is uniformly Lipschitz with respect to u;
-
(iii)
\(\Phi(x)\) is uniformly Lipschitz with respect to x.
Assumption 2
There exists constants \(c_{2}\), \(c_{2}^{\prime}\), \(c_{3}\) such that
and
where \(c_{2}\), \(c_{2}^{\prime}\), and \(c_{3}\) are given positive constants.
Now we give the main result of our paper.
Theorem 2
Let Assumptions 1 and 2 hold. Then there exists a unique adapted solution \((X,Y,Z)\) of FBSDE (1).
Proof of uniqueness
Let \(U^{1}=(X^{1},Y^{1},Z^{1})\) and \(U^{2}=(X^{2},Y^{2},Z^{2})\) be two adapted solutions of FBSDE (1). We set
Then we have
From Assumption 1 it follows that
Using the Itô product rule of semimartingales, we have
where \(d(G\hat{X_{s}})\,d\hat{Y_{s}}=d[G\hat{X_{s}},\hat{Y_{s}}]_{t}\), and hence, taking expectation and evaluating at \(t=T\), by Assumption 2 we get
Then we deduce that
Since \(c_{2}\), \(c_{2}^{\prime}\), and \(c_{3}\) are given positive constants, we have \(|G\hat{X}|^{2}\equiv0\), \(|G^{*}\hat{Y}|^{2}\equiv0\), \(|G^{*}\hat {Z}|^{2}\equiv0 \). So \(\hat{X}_{s}^{1}\equiv\hat{X}_{s}^{2}\), \(\hat {Y}_{s}^{1}\equiv\hat{Y}_{s}^{2}\), \(\hat{Z}_{s}^{1}\equiv\hat{Z}_{s}^{2}\), \(d \langle M,M \rangle_{t}\times P\)-a.s. □
We now consider the following family of FBSDEs parameterized by \(l\in[0,1]\):
where ϕ, ψ, and γ are given processes in \(M^{2}(0,T)\) with values in \(R^{n}\), \(R^{n\times d}\), and \(R^{m}\), respectively. Clearly, when \(l=1\), \(\xi\equiv0\), the existence of a solution of FBSDE (3) implies the existence of that of FBSDE (1). When \(l=0\) in FBSDE (3), it is
For proving the existence part of the theorem, we first need the following two lemmas.
Lemma 2
The following equation has a unique solution:
where λ is a nonnegative constant.
Proof
We note that the matrix G is of full rank. The proof of the existence for FBSDE (5) can be divided into two cases, \(n\leq m\) and \(n>m\).
For the first case, the matrix \(G^{*}G\) is of full rank. Let
Multiplying \(G^{*}\) for \((Y,Z)\) on both sides of the BSDE yields
Similarly, multiplying \((I_{m}-G(G^{*}G)^{-1}G^{*})\) on both sides of the same equation gives
Obviously, the pair \((Y^{\prime\prime},Z^{\prime\prime})\) is uniquely determined (see Cohen and Elliott [4]). The uniqueness of \((X^{\prime},Y^{\prime},Z^{\prime})\) follows from Theorem 2. In order to solve FBSDE (6), we introduce the following \(n\times n\)-symmetric matrix-valued ODE, which is known as the matrix-Riccati equation:
It is well known that this equation has a unique nonnegative solution \(K \in C^{1}([0,T);S^{n})\), where \(S^{n}\) stands for the space of all \(n\times n\)-symmetric matrices. We then study the solution \((p,q) \in M^{2}(0,T;R^{n+n\times d})\) of the following linear simple BSDE:
We now consider \(X_{t}^{\prime}\) as the solution of the SDE
Then we can easily check that \((X_{t}^{\prime},Y_{t}^{\prime},Z_{t}^{\prime})=(X_{t}^{\prime},K(t)X_{t}^{\prime}+p_{t},q_{t})\) is a solution of FBSDE (6). Once \((X^{\prime},Y^{\prime},Z^{\prime})\) and \((Y^{\prime\prime},Z^{\prime\prime})\) are resolved, we can obtain the triple \((X,Y,Z)\) uniquely by
For the second case, the matrix \(GG^{*}\) is of full rank. We set
where \(X^{\prime\prime}\) is the unique solution of the following linear SDE:
The triple \((X^{\prime},Y^{\prime},Z^{\prime})\) solves the FBSDE
In order to solve this equation, we introduce the following \(m\times m\)-symmetric matrix-valued matrix-Raccati equation:
It is well known that this equation has a unique nonnegative solution \(K \in C^{1}([0,T);S^{m})\), where \(S^{m}\) stands for the space of all \(m\times m\)-symmetric matrices. We then look for the solution \((p,q) \in M^{2}(0,T;R^{m+m\times d})\) of the following linear simple BSDE:
We now let \(X_{t}^{\prime}\) be the solution of the following SDE:
Then we can easily check that \((X_{t}^{\prime},Y_{t}^{\prime},Z_{t}^{\prime})=(X_{t}^{\prime},K(t)X_{t}^{\prime}+p_{t},q_{t})\) is a solution of FBSDE (7). Once \((X^{\prime},X^{\prime\prime}, Y^{\prime},Z^{\prime})\) are resolved, then by the definition we can obtain the triple \((X,Y,Z)\) uniquely as
The proof is complete. □
Lemma 3
We assume Assumptions 1 and 2. If for an \(l_{0}\in[0,1)\), there exists a solution \((X^{l_{0}},Y^{l_{0}},Z^{l_{0}})\) of FBSDE (3), then there exists a positive constant \(\delta_{0}\) such that for each \(\delta\in [0,\delta_{0}]\), there exists a solution \((X^{l_{0}+\delta },Y^{l_{0}+\delta},Z^{l_{0}+\delta})\) of FBSDE (3) for \(l=l_{0}+\delta\).
Proof
Since for all \(\phi\in M^{2}(0,T; \mathbb{R}^{n})\), \(\gamma\in M^{2}(0,T; \mathbb{R}^{m})\), \(\psi\in M^{2}(0,T; \mathbb{R}^{n\times d})\), \(\xi\in L^{2}(\Omega, \mathscr{F}_{T}, \mathbb{P})\), \(x\in\mathbb{R}^{n}\), \(l_{0}\in[0,1)\), there exists a unique solution of (3), for every \(U_{s}=(X_{s}, Y_{s}, Z_{s})\in M^{2}(0,T; \mathbb{R}^{n+m+m\times d})\), there exists a unique triple \(u_{s}=(x_{s}, y_{s}, z_{s})\in M^{2}(0,T; \mathbb{R}^{n+m+m\times d})\) satisfying the following FBSDE:
We want to prove that the mapping defined by
is a contraction.
Let \(U^{\prime}\times X_{T}^{\prime}=(X^{\prime},Y^{\prime},Z^{\prime})\times X_{T}^{\prime} \in M^{2}(0,T; \mathbb{R}^{n+m+m\times d})\times L^{2}(\Omega,\mathscr{F}_{T}, \mathbb{P})\) and \(u^{\prime}\times x_{T}^{\prime}=I_{l_{0}+\delta}(U^{\prime} \times X_{T}^{\prime})\). We set
Then
Using the Itô product rule of semimartingales for the product \((G\hat{x}_{s}, \hat{y}_{s})\), taking expectations, and evaluating at \(t=T\) yield
By Assumptions 1 and 2, since \(c_{2}>0\) and \(c_{3}>0\), we obtain
For the difference of the solutions \((\hat{y},\hat {z})=(y-y^{\prime},z-z^{\prime})\), we apply the usual technique to the BSDE and derive that
Similarly, for the difference of the solution \(\hat{x}=x-x^{\prime}\), we apply the usual technique to the forward part:
Here the constant \(c_{4}\) depends on the Lipschitz constants, and so do G, \(c_{2}\), \(c_{2}^{\prime}\), and T.
Combing the above estimates, we get
where the constant \(c_{5}\) depends on \(c_{4}\), G, \(c_{2}\), and \(c_{3}\). If we choose \(\delta_{0}=\frac{1}{2c_{5}}\), then clearly for each fixed \(\delta\in[0, \delta_{0}]\), the mapping \(I_{\alpha+\delta}\) is a contraction in the sense that
This indicates that this mapping has a unique fixed point \((u^{l_{0}+\delta})=(x^{l_{0}+\delta}, y^{l_{0}+\delta}, z^{l_{0}+\delta})\), which is a solution of FBSDE (3) for \(l=l_{0}+\delta\). The proof is complete. □
Proof of existence
From Lemma 2 we immediately see that, when \(\lambda=1\) in FBSDE (5), FBSDEs (3) for \(l=0\) (that is, FBSDE (4)) has a unique solution. It then follows from Lemma 3 that there exists a positive constant \(\delta_{0}\) depending on Lipschitz constants, \(c_{2}\), \(c_{2}^{\prime}\), \(c_{3}\), and T such that, for each \(\delta\in[0,\delta_{0}]\), FBSDEs (3) for \(l=l_{0}+\delta\) has a unique solution. We can repeat this process for N times with \(1\leq N \delta_{0}<1+\delta_{0}\). It then follows that, in particular, FBSDE (3) for \(l=1\) with \(\xi \equiv0\) has a unique solution. The proof is complete. □
5 Another existence and uniqueness theorem
Next, we give another existence and uniqueness theorem. First, we give another assumption.
Assumption 3
There exist constants \(c_{2}\), \(c_{2}^{\prime}\), \(c_{3}\) such that
and
where \(c_{2}\), \(c_{2}^{\prime}\), and \(c_{3}\) are given positive constants.
Theorem 3
Let Assumptions 1 and 3 hold. Then there exists a unique adapted solution \((X,Y,Z)\) for FBSDE (1).
Proof of uniqueness
Using the same procedure as in the proof of uniqueness of Theorem 2, by Assumption 3 we get
Thus, we deduce that
Since \(c_{2}\), \(c_{2}^{\prime}\), and \(c_{3}\) are given positive constants, we have \(|G\hat{X}|^{2}\equiv0\), \(|G^{*}\hat{Y}|^{2}\equiv0\), \(|G^{*}\hat {Z}|^{2}\equiv0 \). So \(\hat{X}_{s}^{1}\equiv\hat{X}_{s}^{2}\), \(\hat {Y}_{s}^{1}\equiv\hat{Y}_{s}^{2}\), \(\hat{Z}_{s}^{1}\equiv\hat{Z}_{s}^{2}\), \(d \langle M,M \rangle_{t}\times P\)-a.s. □
We now consider the following family of FBSDEs parameterized by \(l\in[0,1]\):
where ϕ, ψ, and γ are given processes in \(M^{2}(0,T)\) with values in \(R^{n}\), \(R^{n\times d}\), and \(R^{m}\), respectively. Clearly, when \(l=1\) and \(\xi\equiv0\), the existence of a solution of FBSDE (8) implies that of FBSDE (1). When \(l=0\) in FBSDEs (8), it is
For proving the existence part of the theorem, we first need the following two lemmas.
Lemma 4
The following equation has a unique solution:
where λ is a nonnegative constant.
Lemma 5
Let Assumptions 1 and 3 hold. If for an \(l_{0}\in[0,1)\), there exists a solution \((X^{l_{0}},Y^{l_{0}},Z^{l_{0}})\) of FBSDE (8), then there exists a positive constant \(\delta_{0}\) such that for each \(\delta\in [0,\delta_{0}]\), there exists a solution \((X^{l_{0}+\delta },Y^{l_{0}+\delta},Z^{l_{0}+\delta})\) of FBSDE (8) for \(l=l_{0}+\delta\).
Remark 1
The proofs of Lemma 4 and Lemma 5 are similar to those of Lemma 2 and Lemma 3.
Proof of existence
From Lemma 4 we immediately see that when \(\lambda=1\) in FBSDE (10), FBSDE (8) for \(l=0\) (that is, FBSDE (9)) has a unique solution. It then follows from Lemma 5 that there exists a positive constant \(\delta_{0}\) depending on the Lipschitz constants, \(c_{2}\), \(c_{2}^{\prime}\), \(c_{3}\), and T such that, for each \(\delta\in[0,\delta_{0}]\), FBSDE (8) for \(l=l_{0}+\delta\) has a unique solution. We can repeat this process for N times with \(1\leq N \delta_{0}<1+\delta_{0}\). It then follows that, in particular, FBSDEs (8) for \(l=1\) with \(\xi\equiv0\) has a unique solution.
The proof is complete. □
6 Application to stochastic optimal control problems
In this section, we give an application of the theorem to the stochastic maximum principle in optimal control problems through an example of the linear quadratic case. Consider a continuous-time finite-state Markov chain \(m=\{m_{t},t\in [0,T]\}\). We identify the states of the process with the unit vectors \(e_{i}\) in \(\mathbb{R}^{k}\), where k is the number of states of the chain. The rate matrix of \(m_{t}\) is denoted by \(\mathcal{A}_{t}\).
All the stochastic processes are defined on the filtered probability space \((\Omega,\mathscr{F},\mathscr{F}_{t},\mathbb{P})\), where \(\{\mathscr{F}_{t}\}\) is the completed natural filtration generated by the σ-fields \(\sigma(\{m_{s},s\leq t \},F\in\mathscr{F}_{T}:\mathbb{P}(F)=0)\), and \(\mathscr{F}=\mathscr{F}_{T}\). As noted before, the martingale \(M_{t}=m_{t}-m_{0}-\int_{0}^{t}\mathcal {A}_{s}m_{s}\,ds\) is used to drive the controlled state process \(X_{t}\). Next, we define the function \(\Lambda:[0,T]\times\{e_{i}|i=1,2,\ldots,k\} \rightarrow \mathcal{S}^{k}\) by
Note that
Consider the one-dimensional linear quadratic optimal control problem
and the cost function
where the parameters A, B, Q, R, G are positive constant numbers, and C, D are \(\mathbb{R}^{1\times k}\) vectors.
Denote \(\mathcal {U}=\{u:[0,T]\times\Omega\rightarrow\mathbb{R}\mid u \mbox{ is } \{ \mathscr{F}_{t}\}\mbox{-predictable}, E\int_{0}^{T}|u(s)|^{2}\,ds<+\infty \}\). The stochastic control problem is to find an optimal control \(u^{*}\in\mathcal{U}\) such that
In order to solve the problem, we define the Hamiltonian \(\mathcal {H}:[0,T]\times\mathbb{R} \times\mathbb{R}\times\mathbb{R}\times \mathbb{R}^{1\times k}\times\{e_{i}|i=1,2,\ldots,k\} \rightarrow \mathbb{R}\) by
The adjoint equation is given by the following BSDE:
Then the sufficient stochastic maximum principle is stated as follows.
Theorem 4
Given the assumptions on the parameters above, the coupled FBSDE
exists a unique solution \((\hat{X}_{t},\hat{p}_{t},\hat{s}_{t})\). Moreover, the stochastic linear quadratic problem is solvable with the optimal controlled state process \(\hat{X}_{t}\) and the optimal control defined by
Proof
First, it is easy to check that FBSDE (14) satisfies Assumptions 1 and 3. So, according to Theorem 3, there exists a unique adapted solution \((\hat{X}_{t},\hat{p}_{t},\hat{s}_{t})\in\mathcal {M}^{2}(0,T;\mathbb{R}\times\mathbb{R}\times\mathbb{R}^{1\times k})\). So, according to (15), \(\hat{u}\in\mathcal {U}\), and XÌ‚ is the corresponding state process. Next, for any fixed \(u\in\mathcal{U}\) with the corresponding state process \(X_{t}\), consider
Since \(G>0\), we have
Notice that
for some local martingale L (see [5]). So
By the definition of \(\mathcal{H}\) we have
Adding the two equations, we have
By the convexity of \(\frac{1}{2}Qx^{2}\) and the fact that \(\hat {u}_{t}=-R^{-1}(B \hat{p}_{t-}+D \Lambda(t,m_{t}) \hat{s}_{t}^{*})\) we get the minimum point of the function \(F(u)=\frac{1}{2}Ru_{t}^{2}+Bu_{t}\hat{p}_{t-}+Du_{t}\Lambda(t,m_{t})\hat{s}_{t}^{*}\). Therefore, we conclude that
which proves that û is optimal. □
Remark 2
Differently from the Brownian motion case, the optimal control and the Hamiltonian additionally depend on the state of the Markov chain. This is because Markov chains are discontinuous stochastic processes with finite variation and the quadratic processes of the martingales generated by Markov chains are quite different from the continuous-time diffusions.
References
Pardoux, E, Peng, S: Adapted solution of a backward stochastic differential equations. Syst. Control Lett. 14, 55-61 (1990)
Tang, S, Li, X: Necessary conditions for optimal control of stochastic systems with random jumps. SIAM J. Control Optim. 32(5), 1447-1475 (1994)
Nualart, D, Schoutens, W: Backward stochastic differential equations and Feynman-Kac formula for Levy processes, with applications in finance. Bernoulli 7(5), 761-776 (2001)
Cohen, S, Elliott, R: Solutions of backward stochastic differential equations on Markov chains. Commun. Stoch. Anal. 2(2), 251-262 (2008)
Cohen, S, Elliott, R: Comparisons for backward stochastic differential equations on Markov chains and related no-arbitrage conditions. Ann. Appl. Probab. 20(1), 267-311 (2010)
Cohen, S, Hu, Y: Ergodic BSDEs driven by Markov chains. SIAM J. Control Optim. 51(5), 4138-4168 (2013)
Ma, J, Yong, J: Forward-Backward Stochastic Differential Equations and Their Applications. Lecture Notes in Mathematics. Springer, Berlin (1999)
Buchdahn, R, Hu, Y: Hedging contingent claims for a large investor in an incomplete market. Adv. Appl. Probab. 30(1), 239-255 (1998)
Hu, Y: Potential kernels associated with a filtration and forward-backward SDEs. Potential Anal. 10(2), 103-118 (1999)
Antonelli, F: Backward-forward stochastic differential equations. Ann. Appl. Probab. 3, 777-793 (1993)
Pardoux, E, Tang, S: Forward-backward stochastic differential equations and quasilinear parabolic PDEs. Probab. Theory Relat. Fields 114(2), 123-150 (1999)
Ma, J, Protter, P, Yong, J: Solving forward-backward stochastic differential equations explicitly: a four step scheme. Probab. Theory Relat. Fields 98(3), 339-359 (1994)
Hu, Y, Peng, S: Solutions of forward-backward stochastic differential equations. Probab. Theory Relat. Fields 103(2), 273-283 (1995)
Peng, S, Wu, Z: Fully coupled forward-backward stochastic differential equations. SIAM J. Control Optim. 37(3), 825-843 (1999)
Yong, J: Forward-backward stochastic differential equations with mixed initial-terminal conditions. Trans. Am. Math. Soc. 362(2), 1047-1096 (2010)
Ma, J, Wu, Z, Zhang, D, Zhang, J: On wellposedness of forward-backward SDEs: a unified approach. Ann. Appl. Probab. 25(4), 2168-2214 (2015)
Briand, P, Hu, Y: Probabilistic approach to singular perturbations of semilinear and quasilinear parabolic PDEs. Nonlinear Anal., Theory Methods Appl. 35(7), 815-831 (1999)
Zhang, X, Elliott, R, Siu, T: A stochastic maximum principle for a Markov regime-switching jump-diffusion model and its application to finance. SIAM J. Control Optim. 50, 964-990 (2012)
Crepey, S, Matoussi, A: Reflected and doubly reflected BSDEs with jumps: a priori estimates and comparison. Ann. Appl. Probab. 18, 2041-2069 (2008)
Crepey, S: About the Pricing Equations in Finance. Paris-Princeton Lectures on Mathematical Finance. Springer, Berlin (2010)
Tao, R, Wu, Z, Zhang, Q: BSDEs with regime switching: weak convergence and applications. J. Math. Anal. Appl. 407, 97-111 (2013)
Tao, R, Wu, Z: Maximum principle for optimal control problems of forward-backward regime-switching system and applications. Syst. Control Lett. 61, 911-917 (2012)
Tao, R, Wu, Z, Zhang, Q: Optimal switching under a regime-switching model with two-time-scale Markov chains. Multiscale Model. Simul. 13, 99-131 (2015)
Elliott, R, Aggoun, L, Moore, J: Hidden Markov Models: Estimation and Control. Springer, Berlin (1994)
Acknowledgements
This research are supported by School of Mathematical Sciences project (shxzhxxm201503) of Shandong Normal University, National Natural Science Foundation project (11301309) of China, National Natural Science Foundation project (11201271) of China, and Shandong Provincial Scientific Research Foundation for Excellent Young Scientists (BS2013SF003). We would like to thank the reviewers, whose careful reading, help suggestions, and valuable comments helped us to improve the manuscript.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
Competing interests
The authors declare that they have no competing interests.
Authors’ contributions
All authors jointly worked on the results, and they read and approved the final manuscript.
Rights and permissions
Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.
About this article
Cite this article
Ji, S., Liu, H. & Xiao, X. Fully coupled forward-backward stochastic differential equations on Markov chains. Adv Differ Equ 2016, 133 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1186/s13662-016-0859-6
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s13662-016-0859-6
Keywords
- forward-backward stochastic differential equations
- monotone assumption
- Markov chain