Skip to main content

Theory and Modern Applications

Mean-field anticipated BSDEs driven by time-changed Lévy noises

Abstract

The objective of this work is to show a new kind of mean-field anticipated backward stochastic differential equation (in short MF-ABSDE) driven by time-changed Lévy noises. We give two methods to prove the existence and uniqueness of the solution of those equations by the fixed point theorem and the Picard iterative sequence. Finally, we obtain a comparison theorem for the solutions.

1 Introduction

With the pioneering work of Pardoux and Peng [13], different properties of backward stochastic differential equations (in short BSDEs) in wider areas have attracted many researchers’ great interests. Applying these results to finance, biology and physics, such processes appear in many different applications. Many achievements have been made in the research of BSDEs in a more general framework. We note there are several constructions of BSDEs in the literature. See e.g. El Karou et al. [5], Peng [14], Buckdahn et al. [2] and Douissi et al. [4]. In mathematical terms, following for instance Peng and Yang [15], this amounts to solving a fundamental class of BSDE, called anticipated BSDE; that is,

$$\begin{aligned} \textstyle\begin{cases} Y_{t}=\xi _{T}+\int _{t}^{T}f(s, Y_{s}, Z_{s}, Y_{s+u(s)}, Z_{s+v(s)})\,ds- \int _{t}^{T}Z_{s}\,dW_{s} ; \\ Y_{t}=\xi _{t}, \quad t\in [T, T+K]; \\ Z_{t}=\eta _{t}, \quad t\in [T, T+K], \end{cases}\displaystyle \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where \(u(t), v(t)\in C [0, T]\) and they satisfy

  1. (A1)

    \(\exists K>0\), \(\forall t\in [0,T] \) such that

    $$ t+u(t) \leq T+K, \quad\quad t+v(t)\leq T+K; $$
  2. (A2)

    \(\exists L>0\), \(\forall t\in [0, T]\), \(g(t)\geq 0\) and \(g(t)\in L[0,T+K] \) such that

    $$ \int _{t}^{T}g \bigl(s+u(s) \bigr)\,ds\leq L \int _{t}^{T+K}g(s)\,ds,\quad\quad \int _{t}^{T}g \bigl(s+v(s) \bigr)\,ds \leq L \int _{t}^{T+K}g(s)\,ds. $$

Clearly we note that the generator \(f(\cdot )\) contains many values \((Y_{t}, Z_{t})\) of current time and future time in Eq. (1). And the authors dealt with the fact that the anticipated BSDE has a unique result and established a comparison theorem for the solution. Also, they verified by a duality relationship between anticipated BSDEs and stochastic differential delay equations. Using the duality, they solved some stochastic optimal control problems (see e.g. Xu [20], Yu [21], Giulia and Steffen [7], Klimsiak [9], Wang [19], Wang, Shi and Meng [18], Zhang and Yan [22], among others).

Furthermore, Lu and Ren [12] studied anticipated backward stochastic differential equations on Markov chains. Richter [17] studied a rich and flexible kind of quadratic BSDEs involving affine processes and explicated up to the solution of an ODE in detail. Frei [6] established a new notion of local solution ofq BSDEs and quoted the implications in a financial context. Based on the work of Ren and Mohamed [16], Kallsen and Muhle-Karbe [8], Di Nunno and Sjursen (2014) [3] studied a kind of BSDEs when the noises are time-changing Lévy noises and the generator \(f(\cdot )\) is linear. In the article they also gave the mean-variance portfolio selection.

Very recently, Liu and Ren [11] considered anticipated BSDE for time-changed Lévy noises of the type

$$\begin{aligned} \textstyle\begin{cases} Y_{t}=\xi _{T}+\int _{t}^{T}f(s,\lambda _{s}, Y_{s}, Z_{s}, Y_{s+u(s)}, Z_{s+v(s)})\,ds-\int _{t}^{T}Z_{s}(x)\mu (ds,dx); \\ Y_{t}=\xi _{t}, \quad t\in [T, T+K]; \\ Z_{t}=\eta _{t},\quad t\in [T, T+K], \end{cases}\displaystyle \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where μ is the structure of the mixture of a conditional Brownian measure and a doubly stochastic Poisson measure as follows:

$$ \mu (\alpha ):=B \bigl(\alpha \cap [0,T]\times \{0\} \bigr)+\tilde{H} \bigl( \alpha \cap [0,T]\times \bigl\{ \mathbb{R}\setminus \{0\} \bigr\} \bigr). $$

They talked about the classical problem of the solutions in depth and showed the connection between the two kinds of equations. Liu [10] continued the study of these equations. He gave a direct proof using useful a priori estimates of the solution and included some applications of the classical Feynman–Kac formula.

On the other hand, mean-field limits have played a very important role in different fields of physics and chemistry, but have found in recent work also application in economics and game theory (Buckdahn et al. [2]). Specifically, as far as we are aware of, mean-field limits also have been researched in the context of their applications, such as the optimal control problem, the McKean–Vlasov equation and stochastic games. More and more scholars begin to study stochastic systems with mean-field interaction. Buckdahn et al. [2] investigated mean-field SDEs associated McKean–Vlasov forward SPEs and PDEs. Buckdahn et al. [1] studied the optimal control problem for a kind of general mean-field SDEs. Douissi et al. [4] researched a related stochastic optimal control problem of MF-BSDEs when the noises are fractional Brownian.

In our approach here we are concerned with a kind of MF-ABSDE driven by time-changing Lévy noises, it follows that

$$ \textstyle\begin{cases} Y_{t} =\xi _{T}+\int _{t}^{T}E'[f(s,\lambda _{s},Y_{s},Z_{s},Y'_{s},Z'_{s},Y_{s+u(s)},Z_{s+v(s)},Y'_{s+u(s)},Z'_{s+v(s)})]\,ds \\ \hphantom{Y_{t} =}{}-\int _{t}^{T}Z_{s}(x)\mu (ds,dx); \\ Y_{t}=\xi _{t}, \quad t\in [T,T+K] ; \\ Z_{t}=\eta _{t}, \quad t\in [T,T+K]. \end{cases} $$
(3)

The main objective of this manuscript is the profound study of the anticipated BSDEs (e.g. Liu (2016), [10]). We study the equation in the sense of mean-field limits. In other words, the aim of this manuscript is to discuss some applications of the mean-field anticipated backward stochastic differential equation driven by time-changing Lévy noises. One of the motivations is to study the solution of MF-ABSDE (3). And we give two methods to prove the existence and uniqueness of this solution. Finally, we explore the comparison theorem.

An outline of the paper is as follows: Sect. 2 is devoted to recalling of concepts and auxiliary results. In Sect. 3, we present the existence and uniqueness of the solution for the MF-ABSDE with two methods. In Sect. 4, we obtain the comparison theorem of the solutions.

2 The framework

The aim of this section is to present some concepts and notation. For more details, one can see Buckdahn, Li and Peng [2], Di Nunno and Sjursen [3], Douissi, Wen and Shi [4] and the references therein.

Suppose \(X:=[0,T]\times \mathbb{R}=([0,T]\cup \{0\})\cup ([0,T]\times \{ \mathbb{R}\setminus \{0\}\})\). and let \((\bar{\Omega },\bar{\mathcal{F}},\bar{P}):=(\Omega \times \Omega , \mathcal{F}\otimes \mathcal{F},P\otimes P)\) be the product of \((\Omega ,\mathcal{F},P)\) with itself. Suppose \(T>0\), let \(\lambda _{t}:=(\lambda _{t}^{B},\lambda _{t}^{H})\geq 0 \) be a two-dimensional stochastic process satisfying

  1. (B1)

    \(\forall \epsilon >0\), \(\forall t\in [0,T]\), \(\lim_{\Delta t \rightarrow 0}P ( \vert \lambda ^{k}_{t+\Delta t}-\lambda ^{k}_{t} \vert \geq \epsilon )=0\), \(k=B,H\);

  2. (B2)

    \(E[\int ^{T}_{0}\lambda _{t}^{k}\,dt]<+\infty \), \(k=B,H \).

Consider the following mixture of measures:

$$\begin{aligned} \Lambda (\alpha ) :=& \int _{0}^{T}\mathbf{1}_{\{(s,0)\in \alpha \}}(s) \lambda _{s}^{B}\,ds + \int _{0}^{T} \int _{\mathbb{R}_{0}}\mathbf{1}_{ \alpha }(s,x)q(dx)\lambda _{s}^{H}\,ds \\ =&\Lambda ^{B} \bigl(\alpha \cap [0,T]\times \{0\} \bigr)+\Lambda ^{H} \bigl(\alpha \cap [0,T]\times \bigl\{ \mathbb{R}\setminus \{0\} \bigr\} \bigr), \end{aligned}$$

where \(\alpha \subseteq X\), and q is a deterministic, σ-finite measure on \(\mathcal{B}\{\mathbb{R}\setminus \{0\}\}\) such that

$$ \int _{\mathbb{R}_{0}}z^{2}q(dx)< +\infty . $$

Let we now define the noises driving (3),

Definition 1

B is a random measure on \(\mathcal{B}\{[0,T]\times \{0\}\}\). H is a random measure on \(\mathcal{B}\{[0,T]\times \{\mathbb{R}\setminus \{0\}\}\). They satisfy (C1)–(C5).

  1. (C1)

    \(P ({B}(\alpha )\leq t\vert \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda } )=P (B( \alpha )\leq t\vert \Lambda ^{B}(\alpha ) )=\Phi ( \frac{t}{\sqrt{\Lambda ^{B}(\alpha )}} )\), \(t\in \mathbb{R}\), \(\alpha \subseteq [0,T]\times \{0\}\), where \(\Phi (\cdot )\) represents the density function of the standard normal distribution function.

  2. (C2)

    \(P (B(\alpha _{1})\cap B(\alpha _{2})\vert \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda } )=P (B(\alpha _{1})\vert \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda } )\cap P (B(\alpha _{2})\vert \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda } )\) whenever \(\alpha _{1} \cap \alpha _{2}=\phi \), where \(\alpha _{1}, \alpha _{2}\subseteq [0,T]\times \{0\}\).

  3. (C3)

    \(P (H(\alpha )=k\vert \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda } )=P (H(\alpha )=k\vert \Lambda ^{H}(\alpha ) )=\frac{\Lambda ^{H}(\alpha )^{k}}{k!}e^{-{ \Lambda ^{H}(\alpha )}}\), \(k \in \mathbb{N}\), \(\alpha \subseteq [0,T] \times \{\mathbb{R}\setminus \{0\}\}\).

  4. (C4)

    \(P (H(\alpha _{1})\cap H(\alpha _{2})\vert \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda } )= P (H(\alpha _{1})\vert \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda } ) \cap P (H(\alpha _{2})\vert \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda } )\) whenever \(\alpha _{1} \cap \alpha _{2}=\phi \), where \(\alpha _{1}, \alpha _{2}\subseteq [0,T]\times \{\mathbb{R} \setminus \{0\}\}\).

  5. (C5)

    B and H are conditionally independent given \(\mathcal{F}^{\Lambda }\).

Suppose \(\tilde{H}:=H-\Lambda ^{H}\) is the signed random measure of the form

$$ \tilde{H}(\alpha )=H(\alpha )-\Lambda ^{H}(\alpha ), \quad \alpha \subset [0,T]\times \bigl\{ \mathbb{R}\setminus \{0\} \bigr\} . $$

Definition 2

We define the singed random measure μ on the Borel subsets of X by

$$ \mu (\alpha ):=B \bigl(\alpha \cap [0,T]\times \{0\} \bigr)+\tilde{H} \bigl( \alpha \cap [0,T]\times \bigl\{ \mathbb{R}\setminus \{0\} \bigr\} \bigr), \quad \alpha \subseteq X. $$

Clearly, from (C1)–(C5), we get

$$\begin{aligned}& \mathbb{E} \bigl[B(\alpha )\vert \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda } \bigr]=0, \quad\quad \mathbb{E} \bigl[\tilde{H}( \alpha )\vert \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda } \bigr]=0, \quad\quad \mathbb{E} \bigl[ \mu (\alpha )\vert \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda } \bigr]=0, \\& \mathbb{E} \bigl[B(\alpha )^{2}\vert \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda } \bigr]= \Lambda ^{B}(\alpha ), \quad\quad \mathbb{E} \bigl[\tilde{H}(\alpha )^{2} \vert \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda } \bigr]=\Lambda ^{H}( \alpha ),\quad\quad \mathbb{E} \bigl[\mu (\alpha )^{2}\vert \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda } \bigr]=\Lambda ( \alpha ), \end{aligned}$$

and

$$ \mathbb{E} \bigl[\mu (\alpha _{1})\mu (\alpha _{2})\vert \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda } \bigr]= \mathbb{E} \bigl[\mu (\alpha _{1}) \vert \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda } \bigr]\mathbb{E} \bigl[\mu ( \alpha _{2})\vert \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda } \bigr]=0, $$

where \(\alpha _{1}\cap \alpha _{2}=\phi \). So \(\alpha _{1}\) and \(\alpha _{2}\) are orthogonal given \(\mathcal{F}^{\Lambda }\). The random measure B and H are related to a specific form of time change for Brownian motion and a pure Lévy process. To be more specific, for convenience, we define \(\Lambda ^{B}_{t}:=\int ^{t}_{0}\lambda ^{B}_{s}\,ds\) and \(\tilde{\lambda }_{t}^{H}:=\int ^{t}_{0}\lambda ^{H}_{s}\,ds\), \(t\in [0,T]\).

Set \(\mathbb{F}=\{\mathcal{F}_{t},t\in [0,T]\}\), where \(\mathcal{F}_{t}=\bigcap_{r>t}\mathcal{F}^{\mu }_{r}\) and \(\mathcal{F}^{\mu }_{t}=\mathcal{F}^{B}_{t}\vee \mathcal{F}^{H}_{t} \vee \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda }_{t}\). Furthermore, we set \(\mathbb{G}=\{\mathcal{G}_{t},t\in [0,T]\}\) with \(\mathcal{G}_{t}=\mathcal{F}^{\mu }_{t}\vee \mathcal{F}^{\Lambda }\). Indeed it is not a natural choice of filtration because it includes some anticipating information, the future values of \(\Lambda ^{B}\) and \(\Lambda ^{H}\).

We give this product space to the filtration \(\bar{\mathbb{F}}=\{\bar{\mathcal{F}_{t}}=\mathcal{F}\otimes \mathcal{F}_{t},t\in [ 0,T]\}\). A random variable \(\xi \in L^{1}(\Omega ,\mathcal{F},P) \) originally defined on Ω is extended canonically to \(\bar{\Omega }:\xi ^{\prime }(\omega ^{\prime },\omega )=\xi (\omega ^{ \prime })\), \((\omega ^{\prime },\omega )\in \bar{\Omega }=\Omega \times \Omega \). For \(\forall \theta \in (\bar{\Omega },\bar{\mathcal{F}},\bar{P}) \), the variable \(\theta (\cdot ,\omega ):\Omega \rightarrow \mathbb{R}\) is in \(L^{1}(\Omega ,\mathcal{F},P)\), \(\mathbb{P}\)-a.s. and its expectation is denoted by

$$ E^{\prime } \bigl[\theta (\cdot ,\omega ) \bigr]= \int _{\Omega }\theta \bigl(\omega ^{ \prime },\omega \bigr)P \bigl(d\omega ^{\prime } \bigr). $$

Hence we have \(E^{\prime }[\theta ]=E^{\prime }[\theta (\cdot ,\omega )]\in L^{1} ( \Omega ,\mathcal{F},P) \) and

$$ \bar{E} \bigl[\theta (\cdot ,\omega ) \bigr]= \int _{\bar{\Omega }}\theta (\cdot , \omega )\,d\bar{P}= \int _{\Omega }E^{\prime } \bigl[\theta (\cdot ,\omega ) \bigr]P(d \omega )=E \bigl[E^{\prime }(\theta ) \bigr]. $$

Remark 3

For our notation, we consider the following derivation:

$$\begin{aligned}& E^{\prime } \bigl[f \bigl(t,\lambda _{t},Y_{t},Z_{t},Y_{t}^{\prime },Z_{t}^{\prime },Y_{t+u(t)},Z_{t+v(t)},Y^{\prime }_{t+u(t)},Z^{\prime }_{t+v(t)} \bigr) \bigr](\omega ) \\& \quad =E^{\prime } \bigl[f \bigl(t,\lambda _{t},Y_{t}( \omega ),Z_{t}(\omega ),Y_{t}^{\prime },Z_{t}^{\prime },Y_{t+u(t)}( \omega ),Z_{t+v(t)}(\omega ),Y^{\prime }_{t+u(t)},Z^{\prime }_{t+v(t)} \bigr) \bigr] \\& \quad = \int _{\Omega } \bigl[f \bigl(t,\lambda _{t},Y_{t}( \omega ),Z_{t}(\omega ),Y_{t}^{\prime } \bigl(\omega ' \bigr),Z_{t}^{\prime } \bigl(\omega ' \bigr),Y_{t+u(t)}(\omega ),Z_{t+v(t)}( \omega ),Y^{\prime }_{t+u(t)} \bigl(\omega ' \bigr), \\& \quad\quad{} Z^{\prime }_{t+v(t)} \bigl(\omega ' \bigr) \bigr) \bigr]P \bigl(d \omega ' \bigr). \end{aligned}$$

In addition,

$$\begin{aligned}& \begin{aligned} E \bigl\{ E^{\prime } \bigl[f \bigl(t,\lambda _{t},Y_{t}^{\prime },Z_{t}^{\prime },Y^{\prime }_{t+u(t)},Z^{\prime }_{t+v(t)} \bigr) \bigr] \bigr\} &=E \bigl\{ E \bigl[f(t,\lambda _{t},Y_{t},Z_{t},Y_{t+u(t)},Z_{t+v(t)}) \bigr] \bigr\} \\ &=E \bigl[f \bigl(t,\lambda ^{t},Y_{t},Z_{t},Y_{t+u(t)},Z_{t+v(t)} \bigr) \bigr]; \end{aligned} \\ & \begin{aligned} E \bigl\{ E^{\prime } \bigl[f(t,\lambda _{t},Y_{t},Z_{t},Y_{t+u(t)},Z_{t+v(t)}) \bigr] \bigr\} &=E \bigl\{ E \bigl[f(t,\lambda _{t},Y_{t},Z_{t},Y_{t+u(t)},Z_{t+v(t)}) \bigr] \bigr\} \\ &=E \bigl[f(t,\lambda _{t},Y_{t},Z_{t},Y_{t+u(t)},Z_{t+v(t)}) \bigr]. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Here and in the sequel, we shall denote the following two appropriate spaces of processes which are used frequently:

$$\begin{aligned}& \begin{aligned} \bullet \quad S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R}):= {}&\Bigl\{ \phi _{t}(\omega )_{(0 \leq t \leq T+K, \omega \in \Omega )} \text{ real-valued } \mathbb{G}\text{-adapted stochastic process:} \\ &{} \Bigl( \mathbb{E} \Bigl[ \sup_{0\leq t\leq T+K} \bigl\vert \phi _{t}( \omega ) \bigr\vert ^{2} \Bigr] \Bigr) ^{1/2}< +\infty \Bigr\} . \end{aligned} \\ & \begin{aligned} \bullet \quad L^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K; \mathbb{R}):={}& \biggl\{ \varphi _{t}(\omega )_{(0 \leq t \leq T+K, \omega \in \Omega )} \text{ real-valued }\mathbb{G}\text{-adapted stochastic process:} \\ &{} \biggl( \mathbb{E} \biggl[ \int _{0}^{T+K} \bigl\vert \varphi _{s}(0) \bigr\vert ^{2}\lambda _{s}^{B} \,ds+ \int _{0}^{T+K} \int _{\mathbb{R}_{0}} \bigl\vert \varphi _{s}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2}q(dx) \lambda _{s}^{H}\,ds \biggr] \biggr) ^{1/2} \\ &\quad < +\infty \biggr\} . \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Now, we suppose that \(f(t,(\lambda ^{B},\lambda ^{H}),y,z,y^{\prime },z^{\prime },\xi ,\eta , \xi ^{\prime },\eta ^{\prime }): [0,T]\times [0,+\infty )^{2}\times \Omega \times \mathbb{R}^{4}\times S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R}) \times L^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\times S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K; \mathbb{R})\times L^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\rightarrow L^{2}( \mathcal{G}_{t};\mathbb{R})\) are two progressive functions satisfying the non-Lipschitz condition of the form

  1. (H1)

    \(f(t,(\lambda ^{B},\lambda ^{H}),0,0,0,0,0,0,0,0) \in L^{2}_{ \mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\).

  2. (H2)

    For every \(y,y^{\prime },\bar{y},\bar{y}^{\prime }, z,z^{\prime }, \bar{z},\bar{z}^{\prime }\in \mathbb{R}\), \(\xi ,\xi ^{\prime },\bar{\xi },\bar{\xi }^{\prime }\in S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(t,T+K;\mathbb{R})\), \(\eta ,\eta ^{\prime }, \bar{\eta },\bar{\eta }^{\prime }\in L^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(t,T+K;\mathbb{R})\,dt \times d\mathbb{P}\) a.e., \(r,r^{\prime }\in [t,T+K]\), we have

    $$\begin{aligned}& \bigl\vert f \bigl(t, \bigl(\lambda ^{B},\lambda ^{H} \bigr),y,z,y^{\prime },z^{\prime },\xi _{r}, \eta _{r^{\prime }},\xi ^{\prime }_{r},\eta ^{\prime }_{r^{\prime }} \bigr)-f \bigl(s, \bigl( \lambda ^{B},\lambda ^{H} \bigr), \bar{y},\bar{z},\bar{y}^{\prime },\bar{z}^{\prime },\bar{\xi }_{r},\bar{\eta }_{r^{\prime }},\bar{\xi }^{\prime }_{r}, \bar{\eta }^{\prime }_{r^{\prime }} \bigr) \bigr\vert \\ & \quad \leq C \biggl[ \biggl( \vert y-\bar{y} \vert + \bigl\vert z(0)- \bar{z}(0) \bigr\vert \sqrt{\lambda ^{B}}+ \sqrt{ \int _{\mathbb{R}_{0}} \bigl\vert z(x)-\bar{z}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2} q(dx)}\sqrt{ \lambda ^{H}} \biggr) \\ & \quad\quad {} + \biggl( \bigl\vert y^{\prime }-\bar{y}^{\prime } \bigr\vert + \bigl\vert z^{\prime }(0)-\bar{z}^{\prime }(0) \bigr\vert \sqrt{\lambda ^{B}}+\sqrt{ \int _{\mathbb{R}_{0}} \bigl\vert z^{\prime }(x)- \bar{z}^{\prime }(x) \bigr\vert ^{2} q(dx)}\sqrt{\lambda ^{H}} \biggr) \\ & \quad\quad {} +E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \biggl( \vert \xi _{r}-\bar{\xi }_{r} \vert + \bigl\vert \eta _{r^{\prime }}(0)-\bar{\eta }_{r^{\prime }}(0) \bigr\vert \sqrt{\lambda _{r^{\prime }}^{B}}+ \sqrt{ \int _{\mathbb{R}_{0}} \bigl\vert \eta _{r^{\prime }}(x)-\bar{\eta }_{r^{\prime }}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2} q(dx)}\sqrt{\lambda _{r^{\prime }}^{H}} \biggr) \\ & \quad\quad {} +E^{\prime \mathcal{G}_{t}} \biggl( \bigl\vert \xi ^{\prime }_{r}- \bar{\xi }^{\prime }_{r} \bigr\vert + \bigl\vert \eta ^{\prime }_{r^{\prime }}(0)-\bar{\eta }^{\prime }_{r^{\prime }}(0) \bigr\vert \sqrt{\lambda _{r^{\prime }}^{B}} \\ & \quad\quad {} +\sqrt{ \int _{\mathbb{R}_{0}} \bigl\vert \eta ^{\prime }_{r^{\prime }}(x)- \bar{\eta }^{\prime }_{r^{\prime }}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2} q(dx)} \sqrt{\lambda _{r^{\prime }}^{H}} \biggr) \biggr], \end{aligned}$$

where \(C>0\) is a constant.

3 An existence and uniqueness result for MF-ABSDE

The aim of this section is to seek out a pair of processes \((Y(t),Z(t)) \in S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R} )\times L^{2}_{ \mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\) satisfying the mean-field anticipated BSDE (3). According to Liu and Ren [11], Lemma 4, we can easily draw the following conclusion.

Lemma 4

Given a terminal condition \(\xi \in L^{2}(\Omega ,\mathcal{F}_{T},P)\) and \(f(t,\cdot )\) satisfy \(E\int _{0}^{T} \vert f_{0}(t) \vert ^{2}\,dt<+\infty \), \(Y_{t} \in S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\) and \(Z_{t}\in L^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\) is a pair of processes satisfying the following mean-field BSDE:

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{t} =&\xi + \int _{t}^{T} E^{\prime }f_{0}(s) \,ds- \int _{t}^{T} \int _{ \mathbb{R}}Z_{s}(x)\mu (ds,dx) \\ =&\xi + \int _{t}^{T} E^{\prime }f_{0}(s) \,ds- \int _{t}^{T}Z_{s}(0)\,dB_{s}- \int _{t}^{T} \int _{\mathbb{R}_{0}}Z_{s}(x)\tilde{H}(ds,dx), \end{aligned}$$
(4)

for \(\beta >0\), we have

$$\begin{aligned}& \vert Y_{0} \vert ^{2}+E \biggl[ \int _{0}^{T}\frac{\beta }{2}e^{\beta s} \vert Y_{s} \vert ^{2}\,ds+ \int _{0}^{T} \int _{\mathbb{R}}e^{\beta s} \vert Z_{s} \vert ^{2}(x)\Lambda (ds,dx) \biggr] \\& \quad \leq E \biggl[ \vert \xi \vert ^{2}e^{\beta T}+ \frac{2}{\beta } \int _{0}^{T}e^{ \beta s} \bigl\vert E^{\prime }f_{0}(s) \bigr\vert ^{2}\,ds \biggr]. \end{aligned}$$
(5)

Lemma 5

Let \(f(t,\cdot )\) satisfy (H1) and (H2) for each \(t\in [0,T]\). And suppose that \((y_{t}^{(k)},z_{t}^{(k)}), (y_{t}^{\prime (k)}, z_{t}^{\prime (k)}) \in \mathbb{R}^{2}\), \((y_{t+u(t)}^{(k)},z_{t+v(t)}^{(k)}), (y_{t+u(t)}^{ \prime (k)},z_{t+v(t)}^{\prime (k)}) \in S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K; \mathbb{R})\times L^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\) and \(f(t,\cdot ):[0,T]\times [0,+\infty )^{2}\times \Omega \times \mathbb{R}^{4}\times S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\times L^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\times S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R}) \times L^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\rightarrow \mathbb{R}\), \(k=1,2\), we get

$$\begin{aligned}& E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \biggl[ \int _{t}^{T} e^{\beta s} \bigl( E^{ \prime \mathcal{G}_{t}} f \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},y^{(1)}_{s},z^{(1)}_{s},y^{ \prime (1)}_{s},z^{\prime (1)}_{s},y^{(1)}_{s+u(s)},z^{(1)}_{s+v(s)},y^{ \prime (1)}_{s+u(s)},z^{\prime (1)}_{s+v(s)} \bigr) \\& \quad\quad{} -E^{\prime \mathcal{G}_{t}} f \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},y^{(2)}_{s},z^{(2)}_{s},y^{ \prime (2)}_{s},z^{\prime (2)}_{s},y^{(2)}_{s+u(s)},z^{(2)}_{s+v(s)},y^{ \prime (2)}_{s+u(s)},z^{\prime (2)}_{s+v(s)} \bigr) \bigr)\,ds \biggr]^{2} \\& \quad \leq 24 C^{2}(1+L) (T-t)E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \biggl[ \int _{t}^{T+K}e^{ \beta s} \bigl\vert y^{(1)}_{s}-y^{(2)}_{s} \bigr\vert ^{2}\,ds \\& \quad\quad{} + \int ^{T+K}_{t} \int _{\mathbb{R}}e^{\beta s} \bigl\vert z^{(1)}_{t}(x)-z^{(2)}_{t}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2} \Lambda (ds,dx) \biggr]. \end{aligned}$$
(6)

Proof

Using conditions (A1)–(A2) and (H2), we get

$$\begin{aligned}& E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \biggl[ \int _{t}^{T} e^{\beta s} \bigl( E^{\prime \mathcal{G}_{t}} f \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},y^{(1)}_{s},z^{(1)}_{s},y^{\prime (1)}_{s},z^{ \prime (1)}_{s},y^{(1)}_{s+u(s)},z^{(1)}_{s+v(s)},y^{\prime (1)}_{s+u(s)},z^{ \prime (1)}_{s+v(s)} \bigr) \\& \quad \quad {}-E^{\prime \mathcal{G}_{t}} f \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},y^{(2)}_{s},z^{(2)}_{s},y^{ \prime (2)}_{s},z^{\prime (2)}_{s},y^{(2)}_{s+u(s)},z^{(2)}_{s+v(s)},y^{ \prime (2)}_{s+u(s)},z^{\prime (2)}_{s+v(s)} \bigr) \bigr)\,ds \biggr]^{2} \\& \quad \leq C^{2}E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \biggl\{ \int _{t}^{T} e^{\beta s} \biggl[ \biggl( \bigl\vert y^{(1)}_{s}-y^{(2)}_{s} \bigr\vert + \bigl\vert z_{s}^{(1)}(0)-z_{s}^{(2)}(0) \bigr\vert \sqrt{ \lambda ^{B}_{s}} \\& \quad \quad {}+\sqrt{ \int _{\mathbb{R}_{0}} \bigl\vert z_{s}^{(1)}(x)-z_{s}^{(2)}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2} q(dx)}\sqrt{\lambda _{s}^{H}} \biggr) \\& \quad \quad {}+ \biggl( \bigl\vert y_{s}^{\prime (1)}-y_{s}^{\prime (2)} \bigr\vert + \bigl\vert z_{s}^{\prime (1)}(0)-z_{s}^{ \prime (2)}(0) \bigr\vert \sqrt{\lambda ^{B}_{s}}+\sqrt { \int _{\mathbb{R}_{0}} \bigl\vert z_{s}^{ \prime (1)}(x)-z_{s}^{\prime (2)}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2} q(dx)}\sqrt{\lambda _{s}^{H}} \biggr) \\& \quad \quad {}+E^{\mathcal{G}_{s}} \biggl( \bigl\vert y^{(1)}_{s+u(s)}-y^{(2)}_{s+u(s)} \bigr\vert + \bigl\vert z_{s+v(s)}^{(1)}(0)-z_{s+v(s)}^{(2)}(0) \bigr\vert \sqrt{\lambda ^{B}_{s+v(s)}} \\& \quad \quad {}+\sqrt{ \int _{\mathbb{R}_{0}} \bigl\vert z_{s+v(s)}^{(1)}(x)-z_{s+v(s)}^{(2)}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2} q(dx)}\sqrt{\lambda _{s+v(s)}^{H}} \biggr) \\& \quad \quad {}+E^{\prime \mathcal{G}_{s}} \biggl( \bigl\vert y_{s+u(s)}^{\prime (1)}-y_{s+u(s)}^{ \prime (2)} \bigr\vert + \bigl\vert z_{s+v(s)}^{\prime (1)}(0)-z_{s+v(s)}^{\prime (2)}(0) \bigr\vert \sqrt{\lambda ^{B}_{s+v(s)}} \\& \quad \quad {}+\sqrt{ \int _{\mathbb{R}_{0}} \bigl\vert z_{s+v(s)}^{\prime (1)}(x)-z_{s+v(s)}^{ \prime (2)}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2} q(dx)}\sqrt{\lambda _{s+v(s)}^{H}} \biggr) \biggr]^{2} \biggr\} \,ds \\& \quad \leq 24C^{2}(T-t)E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \{ \int _{t}^{T} e^{\beta s} \biggl[ \biggl( \bigl\vert y^{(1)}_{s}-y^{(2)}_{s} \bigr\vert ^{2} \\& \quad \quad {}+ \bigl\vert z_{s}^{(1)}(0)-z_{s}^{(2)}(0) \bigr\vert ^{2}\lambda ^{B}_{s}+ \int _{ \mathbb{R}_{0}} \bigl\vert z_{s}^{(1)}(x)-z_{s}^{(2)}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2} q(dx)\lambda _{s}^{H} \biggr) \\& \quad\quad {} +E^{\mathcal{G}_{s}} \biggl( \bigl\vert y^{(1)}_{s+u(s)}-y^{(2)}_{s+u(s)} \bigr\vert ^{2}+ \bigl\vert z_{s+v(s)}^{(1)}(0)-z_{s+v(s)}^{(2)}(0) \bigr\vert ^{2} \lambda ^{B}_{s+v(s)} \\& \quad\quad {}+ \int _{\mathbb{R}_{0}} \bigl\vert z_{s}^{(1)}(x)-z_{s}^{(2)}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2} q(dx) \lambda _{s+v(s)}^{H} \biggr) \biggr]\,ds \\& \quad \leq 24 C^{2}(1+L) (T-t)E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \biggl[ \int _{t}^{T+K}e^{ \beta s} \bigl\vert y^{(1)}_{s}-y^{(2)}_{s} \bigr\vert ^{2}\,ds \\& \quad\quad {}+ \int ^{T+K}_{t} \int _{\mathbb{R}}e^{\beta s} \bigl\vert z^{(1)}_{s}(x)-z^{(2)}_{s}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2} \Lambda (ds,dx) \biggr]. \end{aligned}$$

 □

Theorem 6

Suppose that \(\xi (t)\in S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(T,T+K;\mathbb{R})\) and \(\eta (t)\in L^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(T,T+K;\mathbb{R})\), (H1) and (H2) hold, \(u(\cdot )\) and \(v(\cdot )\) satisfy (A1) and (A2). The MF-ABSDE (3) has a unique solution \((Y,Z)\), i.e., we have \(Y\in S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\), \(Z\in L^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K; \mathbb{R})\) satisfying MF-ABSDE (3).

Proof

We structure a norm on the space \(S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\times L^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K; \mathbb{R})\) which is equivalent to the following norm:

$$ \bigl\Vert (g, h) \bigr\Vert _{\beta }= \biggl(E \int _{0}^{T+K}e^{\beta s} \vert g_{s} \vert ^{2}\,ds+E \int _{0}^{T+K} \int _{\mathbb{R}}e^{\beta s} \bigl\vert h_{s}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2}\Lambda (ds,dx) \biggr)^{1/2}. $$

We consider the following MF-ABSDE driven by Lévy noises:

$$ \textstyle\begin{cases} Y_{t} =\xi _{T}+\int ^{T}_{t}E'[f(t,\lambda _{t},Y_{t},Z_{t},Y'_{t},Z'_{t},Y_{t+u(t)},Z_{t+v(t)},Y'_{t+u(t)},Z'_{t+v(t)})]\,dt \\ \hphantom{Y_{t} =}{}-\int ^{T}_{t}Z_{t}(x)\mu (dt,dx), \quad t\in [0,T]; \\ Y_{t}=\xi _{t}, \quad t\in [T,T+K] ; \\ Z_{t}=\eta _{t}, \quad t\in [T,T+K]. \end{cases} $$
(7)

For two any elements \((y^{(1)},z^{(1)}), (y^{(2)},z^{(2)})\in S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K; \mathbb{R})\times L^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\), we define a mapping \(\Psi :S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\times L^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K; \mathbb{R})\rightarrow S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\times L^{2}_{ \mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\), that is, \(\Psi [(y,z)]=(Y,Z)\). We introduce the mapping \((Y^{(1)},Z^{(1)})=\Psi [(y^{(1)},z^{(1)})]\) and \((Y^{(2)},Z^{(2)})=\Psi [(y^{(2)},z^{(2)})]\): \(S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K; \mathbb{R})\times L^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\rightarrow S^{2}_{ \mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\times L^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K; \mathbb{R})\) through MF-ABSDEs (7). We put \(\hat{Y}=Y^{(1)}-Y^{(2)}\), \(\hat{Z}=Z^{(1)}-Z^{(2)}\), \(\hat{y}=y^{(1)}-y^{(2)}\), \(\hat{z}=z^{(1)}-z^{(2)}\), and

$$\begin{aligned} E^{\prime \mathcal{G}_{t}}\hat{f}(s) =& E^{\prime \mathcal{G}_{t}} f \bigl(s, \lambda _{s},y^{(1)}_{s},z^{(1)}_{s},y^{\prime (1)}_{s},z^{\prime (1)}_{s},y^{(1)}_{s+u(s)},z^{(1)}_{s+v(s)},y^{ \prime (1)}_{s+u(s)},z^{\prime (1)}_{s+v(s)} \bigr) \\ & {} -E^{\prime \mathcal{G}_{t}} f \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},y^{(2)}_{s},z^{(2)}_{s},y^{ \prime (2)}_{s},z^{\prime (2)}_{s},y^{(2)}_{s+u(s)},z^{(2)}_{s+v(s)},y^{ \prime (2)}_{s+u(s)},z^{\prime (2)}_{s+v(s)} \bigr). \end{aligned}$$

Then we have

$$ \textstyle\begin{cases} d\hat{Y}_{t} =E^{\prime \mathcal{G}_{t}}\hat{f}(t)\,dt-\hat{Z}_{t}(x) \mu (dt,dx), \quad t\in [0,T]; \\ \hat{Y}_{t}=0, \quad t\in [T,T+K]; \\ \hat{Z}_{t}=0, \quad t\in [T,T+K]. \end{cases} $$
(8)

Now we will prove that \(Y\in S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\), \(Z\in L^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K; \mathbb{R})\) solves MF-ABSDE (3) if and only if it is a fixed point of Ψ.

By Lemma 4, we get

$$ E \biggl[ \int _{0}^{T}\frac{\beta }{2}e^{\beta t} \vert \hat{Y}_{s} \vert ^{2}\,ds+ \int _{0}^{T} \int _{\mathbb{R}}e^{\beta t} \vert \hat{Z}_{s} \vert ^{2}(x)\Lambda (ds,dx) \biggr]\leq \frac{2}{\beta }E \biggl( \int _{0}^{T}e^{\beta s} \bigl\vert E^{\prime \mathcal{G}_{s}}\hat{f}(s) \bigr\vert ^{2}\,ds \biggr). $$

Using the fact that \(u(x)\), \(v(x)\) satisfy (A1) and (A2), by Lemma 5, we get

$$\begin{aligned}& E \biggl[ \int _{0}^{T}\frac{\beta }{2}e^{\beta s} \vert \hat{Y}_{s} \vert ^{2}\,ds+ \int _{0}^{T} \int _{\mathbb{R}}e^{\beta s} \vert \hat{Z}_{s} \vert ^{2}(x) \Lambda (ds,dx) \biggr] \\& \quad \leq \frac{2}{\beta }E \biggl\{ \int _{0}^{T} e^{\beta s} \bigl[E^{ \prime \mathcal{G}_{t}} f \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},y^{(1)}_{s},z^{(1)}_{s},y^{ \prime (1)}_{s},z^{\prime (1)}_{s},y^{(1)}_{s+u(s)},z^{(1)}_{s+v(s)},y^{ \prime (1)}_{s+u(s)},z^{\prime (1)}_{s+v(s)} \bigr) \\& \quad\quad {}-E^{\prime \mathcal{G}_{t}} f \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},y^{(2)}_{s},z^{(2)}_{s},y^{ \prime (2)}_{s},z^{\prime (2)}_{s},y^{(2)}_{s+u(s)},z^{(2)}_{s+v(s)},y^{ \prime (2)}_{s+u(s)},z^{\prime (2)}_{s+v(s)} \bigr) \bigr] \biggr\} \\& \quad \leq \frac{48 C^{2}(1+L)(T-t)}{\beta }E \biggl[ \int _{0}^{T+K}e^{ \beta s} \vert \bar{y}_{s} \vert ^{2}\,ds+ \int ^{T+K}_{0} \int _{\mathbb{R}}e^{ \beta s} \bigl\vert \bar{z}_{s}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2} \Lambda (ds,dx) \biggr], \end{aligned}$$

that is,

$$\begin{aligned}& E \biggl[ \int _{0}^{T+K}e^{\beta s} \vert \bar{Y}_{s} \vert ^{2}\,ds+ \int _{0}^{T+K} \int _{\mathbb{R}}e^{\beta s} \vert \bar{Z}_{s} \vert ^{2}(x)\Lambda (ds,dx) \biggr] \\& \quad \leq \frac{48 C^{2}T(1+L)}{\beta }E \biggl[ \int _{0}^{T+K}e^{\beta s} \vert \bar{y}_{s} \vert ^{2}\,ds+ \int ^{T+K}_{0} \int _{\mathbb{R}}e^{\beta s} \bigl\vert \bar{z}_{s}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2} \Lambda (ds,dx) \biggr]. \end{aligned}$$
(9)

Let \(\beta =96 C^{2}T(1+L)+2\), it is very easy for us to find \(\Vert (\hat{Y}, \hat{Z}) \Vert _{\beta }\leq \frac{1}{\sqrt{2}} \Vert ( \hat{y}, \hat{z}) \Vert _{\beta }\). Hence we see that this mapping Ψ is a strict contraction on \(S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\times L^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K; \mathbb{R})\). It follows by the fixed point theorem that Ψ has a unique fixed point, that is, the MF-ABSDE (3) has a unique solution \((Y_{t},Z_{t})\in S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\times L^{2}_{ \mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\) on \([0,T+K]\) such that \(\Psi (Y,Z)=(Y,Z)\). The proof is complete. □

Remark 7

In fact, we almost surely get the solution of the mean-field anticipated BSDE (3) by the Picard iterative sequence.

We suppose that \((Y_{t}^{n},Z^{n}_{t})\) is the sequence defined recursively by \((Y_{t}^{0}=0,Z^{0}_{t}=0)\) and

$$ \textstyle\begin{cases} dY^{n+1}_{t} =-E'[f(t,\lambda _{t},Y^{n}_{t},Z^{n}_{t},Y^{\prime n}_{t},Z^{\prime n}_{t},Y^{n}_{t+u(t)},Z^{n}_{t+v(t)},Y^{\prime n}_{t+u(t)},Z^{\prime n}_{t+v(t)})]\,dt \\ \hphantom{dY^{n+1}_{t} =}{}+Z^{n+1}_{t}(x)\mu (dt,dx), \quad t\in [0,T], \\ Y^{n+1}_{t}=\xi _{t}, \quad t\in [T,T+K] , \\ Z^{n+1}_{t}=\eta _{t}, \quad t\in [T,T+K]. \end{cases} $$
(10)

Then the sequence \((Y^{n}_{t},Z^{n}_{t})\) converges to \((Y(\cdot ),Y(\cdot ))\) when \(n \rightarrow +\infty \).

In fact, suppose \((Y^{n}_{t},Z^{n}_{t})\) is the sequence defined recursively by (10). By (9)

$$ \bigl\Vert Y^{n+1}_{t}-Y^{n}_{t} \bigr\Vert ^{2}+ \bigl\Vert Z^{n+1}_{t}-Z^{n}_{t} \bigr\Vert ^{2} \leq \biggl(\frac{48 C^{2}T(1+L)}{\beta } \biggr)^{n} \bigl( \bigl\Vert Y^{1}_{t}-Y^{0}_{t} \bigr\Vert ^{2}+ \bigl\Vert Z^{1}_{t}-Z^{0}_{t} \bigr\Vert ^{2} \bigr), $$

choosing \(\beta >48 C^{2}T(1+L)\), we find that \(\{Y^{n}_{t}\}\) is a Cauchy sequence in \(S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\) and \(\{Z^{n}_{t}\}\) is a Cauchy sequence in \(L^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(0,T+K;\mathbb{R})\) and the result follows.

4 Comparison theorem

In this section, we will study a kind of mean-field anticipated BSDE driven by time-changing Lévy noises. Let \((Y^{(1)},Z^{(1)})\), \((Y^{(2)},Z^{(2)})\) be, respectively, solutions for the following two one-dimensional mean-field anticipated BSDE:

$$ \textstyle\begin{cases} Y_{t}^{(k)} =\xi _{T}+\int _{t}^{T}E^{\prime }f^{(k)} (s,\lambda _{s},Y^{(k)}_{s},Z^{(k)}_{s},Y^{\prime (k)}_{s+u(s)},Z^{ \prime (k)}_{s+v(s)} )\,ds \\ \hphantom{Y_{t}^{(k)} =}{}-\int _{t}^{T}\int _{\mathbb{R}} Z^{(k)}_{s}(x) \mu (ds,dx), \quad t\in [0,T]; \\ Y^{(k)}_{t}=\xi _{t}^{(k)}, \quad t\in [T,T+K]; \\ Z^{(k)}_{t}=\eta _{t}^{(k)}, \quad t\in [T,T+K]. \end{cases} $$
(11)

That is,

$$\begin{aligned} \textstyle\begin{cases} -dY_{t}^{(k)} =E^{\prime }f^{(k)} (t,\lambda _{t},Y^{(k)}_{t},Z^{(k)}_{t},Y^{ \prime (k)}_{t+u(t)},Z^{\prime (k)}_{t+v(t)} )\,dt-Z_{t}^{(k)}(0)\,dB_{t} \\ \hphantom{-dY_{t}^{(k)} =}{}- \int _{\mathbb{R}_{0}}Z^{(k)}_{t}(x)\tilde{H}(dt,dx), \quad t\in [0,T]; \\ Y^{(k)}_{t}=\xi _{t}^{(k)}, \quad t\in [T,T+K]; \\ Z^{(k)}_{t}=\eta _{t}^{(k)}, \quad t\in [T,T+K], \end{cases}\displaystyle \end{aligned}$$
(12)

where \(k=1,2\).

Theorem 8

Assume that \(f^{(1)}(t,\cdot )\), \(f^{(2)}(t,\cdot )\) satisfy (H1)(H2), \(\xi _{t}^{(1)}, \xi _{t}^{(2)}\in S^{2}_{\mathbb{G}}(T,T+K;\mathbb{R})\) and (A1), (A2) hold for \(u(\cdot )\), \(v(\cdot )\). Assume:

  1. (H3)

    One of the two coefficients is independent of \(z'\).

  2. (H4)

    One of the two coefficients is nondecreasing in \(y'\).

Moreover, we suppose that

  1. (H5)

    \(\xi _{t}^{(1)}\leq \xi _{t}^{(2)} \), \(t\in [T,T+K] \) \(\mathbb{P}\)-a.s.

  2. (H6)

    \(f^{(1)}(t,\cdot )\leq f^{(2)}(t,\cdot ) \) \(\mathbb{P}\)-a.s.

It is then true that \(Y^{(1)}_{t}\leq Y^{(2)}_{t} \) \(\mathbb{P}\)-a.s.

Proof

Without loss of generality, we assume that \(f^{(1)}(t,\cdot )\) is nondecreasing in \(y'\) and \(f^{(2)}(t,\cdot )\) is independent of \(z'\). For notational simplicity we use \(\hat{Y}_{t}=Y_{t}^{(1)}-Y_{t}^{(2)}\), \(\hat{Z}_{t}=Z_{t}^{(1)}-Z_{t}^{(2)}\), \(\hat{\xi }_{t}=\xi _{t}^{(1)}-\xi _{t}^{(2)}\); then the pair \((Y,Z)\) can be regarded as the solution to the mean-field anticipated BSDE

$$ \begin{aligned} -d\hat{Y}_{t} ={}&E^{\prime } \bigl[f^{(1)} \bigl(t,\lambda _{t},Y^{(1)}_{t},Z^{(1)}_{t},Y^{ \prime (1)}_{t+u(t)},Z^{\prime (1)}_{t+v(t)} \bigr)-f^{(2)} \bigl(t, \lambda _{t},Y^{(2)}_{t},Z^{(2)}_{t},Y^{\prime (2)}_{t+u(t)} \bigr) \bigr]\,dt \\ &{}-\hat{Z}_{t}(x)\mu (dt,dx), \quad t\in [0,T]. \end{aligned} $$
(13)

From the Itô formula applied from \(s=t\) to \(s=T\) on \((\hat{Y}_{t}^{+})^{2}\), it follows that

$$\begin{aligned}& E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \bigl\vert \hat{Y}_{t}^{+} \bigr\vert ^{2}+E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \int _{t}^{T} \int _{\mathbb{R}}1_{\{\hat{Y}_{s}>0\}} \bigl\vert \hat{Z}_{s}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2}\Lambda (ds,dx) \\& \quad =2E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \int _{t}^{T}\hat{Y}_{s}^{+}E^{\prime } \bigl[f^{(1)} \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},Y^{(1)}_{s},Z^{(1)}_{s},Y^{\prime (1)}_{s+u(s)},Z^{ \prime (1)}_{s+v(s)} \bigr)-f^{(2)} \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},Y^{(2)}_{s},Z^{(2)}_{s},Y^{ \prime (2)}_{s+u(s)} \bigr) \bigr]\,ds \\& \quad =2E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \int _{t}^{T}\hat{Y}_{s}^{+}E^{\prime } \bigl[f^{(1)} \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},Y^{(1)}_{s},Z^{(1)}_{s},Y^{\prime (1)}_{s+u(s)},Z^{ \prime (1)}_{s+v(s)} \bigr) \\& \quad \quad{}-f^{(1)} \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},Y^{(1)}_{s},Z^{(1)}_{s},Y^{ \prime (2)}_{s+u(s)},Z^{\prime (1)}_{s+v(s)} \bigr) \bigr]\,ds \\& \quad \quad {}+2E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \int _{t}^{T}\hat{Y}_{s}^{+}E^{\prime } \bigl[f^{(1)} \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},Y^{(1)}_{s},Z^{(1)}_{s},Y^{\prime (2)}_{s+u(s)},Z^{ \prime (1)}_{t+v(s)} \bigr)-f^{(2)} \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},Y^{(2)}_{s},Z^{(2)}_{s},Y^{ \prime (2)}_{s+u(s)} \bigr) \bigr]\,ds \\& \quad \leq 2E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \int _{t}^{T}\hat{Y}_{s}^{+}E^{\prime } \bigl[f^{(1)} \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},Y^{(1)}_{s},Z^{(1)}_{s},Y^{\prime (1)}_{s+u(s)},Z^{ \prime (1)}_{s+v(s)} \bigr) \\& \quad \quad{}-f^{(1)} \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},Y^{(1)}_{s},Z^{(1)}_{s},Y^{ \prime (2)}_{s+u(s)},Z^{\prime (1)}_{s+v(s)} \bigr) \bigr]\,ds \\& \quad \quad{} +2E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \int _{t}^{T}\hat{Y}_{s}^{+}E^{\prime } \bigl[f^{(2)} \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},Y^{(1)}_{s},Z^{(1)}_{s},Y^{\prime (2)}_{s+u(s)} \bigr)-f^{(2)} \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},Y^{(2)}_{s},Z^{(2)}_{s},Y^{\prime (2)}_{s+u(s)} \bigr) \bigr]\,ds. \end{aligned}$$

From assumptions (H1)–(H2) and (A1)–(A2), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned}& 2E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \int _{t}^{T}\hat{Y}_{s}^{+}E^{\prime } \bigl[f^{(1)} \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},Y^{(1)}_{s},Z^{(1)}_{s},Y^{\prime (1)}_{s+u(s)},Z^{ \prime (1)}_{s+v(s)} \bigr)-f^{(1)} \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},Y^{(1)}_{s},Z^{(1)}_{s},Y^{ \prime (2)}_{s+u(s)},Z^{\prime (1)}_{s+v(s)} \bigr) \bigr]\,ds \\& \quad \leq 2CE^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \int _{t}^{T}\hat{Y}_{s}^{+}E^{\prime } \bigl(Y^{ \prime (1)}_{s+u(s)}-Y^{\prime (2)}_{s+u(s)} \bigr)^{+}\,ds \\& \quad \leq 2CL \int _{t}^{T} E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \bigl\vert \hat{Y}_{s}^{+} \bigr\vert ^{2}\,ds \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned}& 2E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \int _{t}^{T}\hat{Y}_{s}^{+}E^{\prime } \bigl[f^{(2)} \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},Y^{(1)}_{s},Z^{(1)}_{s},Y^{\prime (2)}_{s+u(s)} \bigr)-f^{(2)} \bigl(s,\lambda _{s},Y^{(2)}_{s},Z^{(2)}_{s},Y^{\prime (2)}_{s+u(s)} \bigr) \bigr]\,dt \\& \quad \leq 2CE^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \int _{t}^{T}\hat{Y}_{s}^{+}E^{\prime } \biggl( \vert \hat{Y}_{s} \vert + \bigl\vert \hat{Z}(0) \bigr\vert \sqrt{\lambda _{s}^{B}}+\sqrt{ \int _{ \mathbb{R}_{0}} \bigl\vert \hat{Z}_{s}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2} q(dx)}\sqrt{\lambda _{s}^{H}} \biggr)\,ds \\& \quad \leq 2C \int _{t}^{T} E^{\mathcal{G}_{s}} \vert \hat{Y}_{s} \vert ^{2}\,ds+2CE^{ \mathcal{G}_{t}} \int _{t}^{T}\hat{Y}_{s}^{+}E^{\prime } \biggl( \bigl\vert \hat{Z}'_{s)}(0) \bigr\vert \sqrt {\lambda _{s}^{B}}+\sqrt{ \int _{\mathbb{R}_{0}} \bigl\vert \hat{Z}'_{s}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2} q(dx)}\sqrt{\lambda _{s}^{H}} \biggr)\,ds \\& \quad \leq \bigl(2C+4C^{2} \bigr) \int _{t}^{T} E^{\mathcal{G}_{s}} \bigl\vert \hat{Y}_{s}^{+} \bigr\vert ^{2}\,ds \\& \quad \quad{}+ \frac{1}{4}E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \int _{t}^{T}1_{\{\hat{Y}_{s}>0\}} \biggl( \bigl\vert \hat{Z}(0) \bigr\vert \sqrt{\lambda _{s}^{B}}+ \sqrt{ \int _{\mathbb{R}_{0}} \bigl\vert \hat{Z}_{s}(x) \bigr\vert q(dx)}\sqrt{\lambda _{s}^{H}} \biggr)^{2} \,ds \\& \quad \leq \bigl(2C+4C^{2} \bigr) \int _{t}^{T} E^{\mathcal{G}_{s}} \bigl\vert \hat{Y}_{s}^{+} \bigr\vert ^{2}\,ds+ \frac{1}{2}E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \int _{t}^{T} \int _{\mathbb{R}}1_{\{\hat{Y}_{s}>0 \}} \bigl\vert \hat{Z}_{s}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2}\Lambda (ds,dx), \end{aligned}$$

where we use the fact that \(2ab\leq ca^{2}+\frac{1}{c} b^{2}\), \(c>0\). We get

$$\begin{aligned} E^{\mathcal{G}_{t}} \bigl\vert \hat{Y}_{t}^{+} \bigr\vert ^{2} \leq &- \frac{1}{2}E^{ \mathcal{G}_{t}} \int _{t}^{T} \int _{\mathbb{R}}1_{\{\hat{Y}_{s}>0\}} \bigl\vert \hat{Z}_{s}(x) \bigr\vert ^{2}\Lambda (ds,dx) \\ & {} + \bigl(2C+2CL+4C^{2} \bigr) \int _{t}^{T} E^{\mathcal{G}_{s}} \bigl\vert \hat{Y}_{s}^{+} \bigr\vert ^{2}\,ds, \quad t \in [0,T]. \end{aligned}$$

Then from Gronwall’s inequality it follows that \(\hat{Y} _{t}= Y_{t}^{(1)}-Y_{t}^{(2)}\leq 0\), \(t\in [0,T]\), \(\mathbb{P}\)-a.s. □

References

  1. Buckdahn, R., Li, J., Ma, J.: A stochastic maximum principle for general mean-field systems. Appl. Math. Optim. 74, 507–534 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00245-016-9394-9

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  2. Buckdahn, R., Li, J., Peng, S.: Mean-field backward stochastic differential equations and related partial differential equations. Stoch. Process. Appl. 119, 3133–3154 (2009)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  3. Di Nunno, G., Sjursen, S.: BSDEs driven by time-changed Lévy noises and optimal control. Stoch. Process. Appl. 124, 1679–1709 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Douissi, S., Wen, J., Shi, Y.: Mean-field anticipated BSDEs driven by fractional Browian motion and related stochastic control problem. Appl. Math. Comput. 355, 282–298 (2019)

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  5. El Karou, N., Peng, S., Quenez, M.C.: Backward stochastic differential equations finance. Math. Finance 7(1), 1–71 (1997)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  6. Frei, C.: Splitting multidimensional BSDEs and finding local equilibria. Stoch. Process. Appl. 124, 2654–2671 (2014)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  7. Giulia, D., Steffen, S.: BSDEs driven by time-changed Lévy noises and optimal control. Stoch. Process. Appl. 124, 1679–1709 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Kallsen, J., Muhle-Karbe, J.: Utility maximization in affine stochastic volatility models. Int. J. Theor. Appl. Finance 13(03), 459–477 (2010)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  9. Klimsiak, T.: Reflected BSDEs with monotone generator. Electron. J. Probab. 107, 1–25 (2012)

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  10. Liu, Y.: Applications of anticipated BSDEs driven by time-changing Lévy noises. J. Inequal. Appl. 2016, 290 (2016)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Liu, Y., Ren, Y.: Anticipated BSDEs driven by time-changed Lévy noises. J. Korean Stat. Soc. 44(3), 403–409 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Lu, W., Ren, Y.: Anticipated backward stochastic differential equations on Markov chains. Stat. Probab. Lett. 83, 1711–1719 (2013)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  13. Pardoux, E., Peng, S.: Adapted solution of a backward stochastic differential equation. Syst. Control Lett. 14, 55–61 (1990)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  14. Peng, S.: Nonlinear expectations and nonlinear Markov chains. Chin. Ann. Math. 26(02), 159–184 (2005)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  15. Peng, S., Yang, Z.: Anticipated backward stochastic differential equations. Ann. Probab. 37, 877–902 (2009)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  16. Ren, Y., Mohamed, E.O.: Generalized reflected BSDEs driven by a Lévy process and an obstacle problem for PDIEs with a nonlinear Neumann boundary condition. J. Comput. Appl. Math. 233, 2027–2043 (2010)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  17. Richter, A.: Explicit solutions to quadratic BSDEs and applications to utility maximization in multivariate affine stochastic volatility models. Stoch. Process. Appl. 124, 3578–3611 (2014)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  18. Wang, M., Shi, Q., Meng, Q.: Optimal control of forward–backward stochastic jump-diffusion differential systems with observation noises: stochastic maximum principle. Asian J. Control 1–14 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1002/asjc.2272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Wang, W.: Optimal control of backward doubly stochastic system. IET Control Theory Appl. 13, 1844–1854 (2019)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  20. Xu, X.: Necessary and sufficient condition for the comparison theorem of multidimensional anticipated backward stochastic differential equations. Sci. China Math. 54, 301–310 (2011)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  21. Yu, Z.: The stochastic maximum principle for optimal control problems of delay systems involving continuous and impulse controls. Automatica 48, 2420–2432 (2012)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  22. Zhang, H., Yan, Z.: Backward stochastic optimal control with mixed deterministic controller and random controller and its applications in linear-quadratic control. Appl. Math. Comput. 369, 1–11 (2020)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank the reviewers for their valuable comments and suggestions, which helped to improve its presentation overall.

Availability of data and materials

Not applicable.

Funding

The research of Youxin Liu is supported by Foundation for Outstanding Young in Higher Education of Anhui of China (gxyq2020119), WHIT Mathematical Modeling Master studio and Anhui University Natural Science Research Project (KJ2019A0976).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

The two authors provided the basic idea of this work. The corresponding author YL wrote the draft of the manuscript, and the other author YD revised the manuscript. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Youxin Liu.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Liu, Y., Dai, Y. Mean-field anticipated BSDEs driven by time-changed Lévy noises. Adv Differ Equ 2020, 621 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1186/s13662-020-03038-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s13662-020-03038-5

Keywords