- Research
- Open access
- Published:
One kind of multiple dimensional Markovian BSDEs with stochastic linear growth generators
Advances in Difference Equations volume 2015, Article number: 265 (2015)
Abstract
In this article, we deal with a multiple dimensional coupled Markovian BSDEs system with stochastic linear growth generators with respect to volatility processes. An existence result is provided by virtue of approximation techniques.
1 Introduction
Backward stochastic differential equations (BSDEs) were proposed firstly by Bismut [1] in linear case to solve the optimal control problems. Later this notion was generalized by Pardoux and Peng [2] into the general nonlinear form, and the existence and uniqueness results were proved under the classical Lipschitz condition. A class of BSDEs was also introduced by Duffie and Epstein [3] in point of view of recursive utility in economics. During the past twenty years, BSDEs theory has attracted many researchers’ interest and has been fully developed into various directions. Among the abundant literature, we refer readers to the florilegium book edited by El-Karoui and Mazliak [4] for the early works before 1996. Surveys on BSDEs theory also include [5] which is written by El-Karoui, Hamadène and Matoussi collected in book [6] (see Chapter 8) and the book by Yong and Zhou [7] (see Chapter 7). Some applications on optimization problems can be found in [5]. About other applications, such as in the field of economics, we refer to El-Karoui, Peng and Quenez [8]. Recently, a complete review on BSDEs theory as well as some new results on nonlinear expectation were introduced in a survey paper by Peng [9].
One possible extension to the pioneering work of [2] is to relax as much as possible the uniform Lipschitz condition on the coefficient. Mao [10] provided an existence and uniqueness result under a weaker condition than the Lipschitz one. Hamadène introduced in [11] a one-dimensional BSDE with local Lipschitz generator. Later Lepeltier and San Martin [12] provided an existence result of minimum solution for one-dimensional BSDE where the generator function f is continuous and of linear growth in terms of \((y, z)\). When f is uniformly continuous in z with respect to \((\omega,t)\) and independent of y, a uniqueness result was obtained by Jia [13]. BSDEs with polynomial growth generator were studied by Briand in [14]. The case of one-dimensional BSDEs with coefficient which is monotonic in y and non-Lipschitz on z is shown in work [15]. About the BSDE with continuous and quadratic growth driver, a classical research should be the one by Kobylanski [16] which investigated a one-dimensional BSDE with driver \(|f(t,y,z)\leq C(1+|y|+|z|^{2})\) and bounded terminal value. This result was generated by Briand and Hu into the unbounded terminal value case in [17].
There are plenty of works on one-dimensional BSDE. However, limited results have been obtained about the multi-dimensional case. We refer to Hamadène, Lepeltier and Peng [18] for an existence result on BSDEs system of Markovian case where the driver is of linear growth on \((y,z)\) and of polynomial growth on the state process. See Bahlali [19, 20] for high-dimensional BSDE with local Lipschitz coefficient.
In the present article, we consider a high-dimensional BSDE under Markovian framework as follows:
for \(i=1,2,\ldots,n\), with process X as a solution of a stochastic differential equation (SDE for short). For each \(i=1,2,\ldots,n\), the coefficient \(H_{i}\) is continuous on \((y^{1},\ldots,y^{n},z^{1},\ldots,z^{n})\) and satisfies
which means that \(H_{i}\) is of stochastic linear growth on \(Z^{i}\), or in other words, it is of linear growth ω by ω. Similar situation was considered in [21] in the background of nonzero-sum stochastic differential game problem. However, in [21], the generator \(H_{i}\) is independent of \((y^{1},\ldots,y^{n})\). According to our knowledge, this general form of high-dimensional coupled BSDEs system with stochastic linear growth generator has not been considered in literature. This is the main motivation of the present work.
The rest of this article is organized as follows. In Section 2, we give some notations and assumptions on the coefficient. The properties of the forward SDE are also provided. The main existence result of BSDEs is proved in Section 3 where a measure domination result plays an important role. This domination result holds true when we assume that the diffusion process of the SDE satisfies the uniform elliptic condition. For the proof of the main result, we adopt an approximation scheme following the well-known mollify technique. The irregular coefficients are approximated by a sequence of Lipschitz functions. Then, we obtain the uniform estimates of the sequence of solutions as well as the convergence result in some appropriate spaces. Finally, we verify that the limit of the solutions is exactly the solution to the original BSDE, which completes the proof.
2 Notations and assumptions
In this section, we give some basic notations, the preliminary assumptions throughout this paper, as well as some useful results. Let \((\Omega, \mathcal{F}, \mathbf{P})\) be a probability space on which we define an m-dimensional Brownian motion \(B=(B_{t})_{0\leq t\leq T}\) with integer \(m\geq1\). Let us denote by \(\mathbf{F }=\{\mathcal{F}_{t}, 0\leq t\leq T\}\) for fixed \(T>0\) the natural filtration generated by process B and augmented by \(\mathcal{N}_{\mathbf{P}}\) the P-null sets, i.e., \(\mathcal{F}_{t}=\sigma\{B_{s}, s\leq t\}\vee\mathcal{N}_{\mathbf{P}}\).
Let \(\mathcal{P}\) be the σ-algebra on \([0,T]\times\Omega\) of \(\mathcal{F}_{t}\)-progressively measurable sets. Let \(p\in[1,\infty)\) be a real constant and \(t\in[0,T]\) be fixed. We then define the following spaces: \(\mathcal{L}^{p}\) = \(\{\xi: \mathcal{F}_{t}\mbox{-measurable and } \mathbf{R}^{m}\mbox{-valued random variable s.t. } \mathbf{E}[|\xi|^{p}]<\infty\}\); \(\mathcal{S}_{t,T}^{p} = \{\varphi=(\varphi_{s})_{t\leq s \leq T} : \mathcal{P} \mbox{-measurable and }\mathbf{R}^{m}\mbox{-valued s.t. } \mathbf{E}[\sup_{s\in[t,T]}|\varphi_{s}|^{p}]< \infty\}\) and \(\mathcal{H}_{t,T}^{p}=\{\varphi=(\varphi_{s})_{t \leq s\leq T}: \mathcal{P}\mbox{-measurable and }\mathbf{R}^{m}\mbox{-valued s.t. }\mathbf{E}[ (\int_{t}^{T}|\varphi_{s}|^{2}\,ds)^{\frac{p}{2}}]< \infty\}\). Hereafter, \(\mathcal{S}_{0,T}^{p}\) and \(\mathcal{H}_{0,T}^{p}\) are simply denoted by \(\mathcal{S}_{T}^{p}\) and \(\mathcal{H}_{T}^{p}\).
The following assumptions are in force throughout this paper. Let σ be the function defined as
which satisfies the following assumption.
Assumption 2.1
-
(i)
σ is uniformly Lipschitz w.r.t. x, i.e., there exists a constant \(C_{1}\) such that, \(\forall t \in[0, T]\), \(\forall x , x^{\prime} \in \mathbf{R}^{m}\), \(| \sigma(t,x)-\sigma(t, x^{\prime})| \leq C_{1} |x- x^{\prime}|\).
-
(ii)
σ is invertible and bounded and its inverse is bounded, i.e., there exists a constant \(C_{\sigma}\) such that \(\forall(t,x)\in[0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\), \(\vert \sigma(t, x)\vert +\vert \sigma^{-1}(t,x)\vert \leq C_{\sigma}\).
Remark 2.1
(Uniform elliptic condition)
Under Assumption 2.1, we can verify that there exists a real constant \(\epsilon>0\) such that for any \((t,x)\in [0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\),
where I is the identity matrix of dimension m.
Suppose that we have a system whose dynamic is described by a stochastic differential equation as follows: for \((t,x)\in[0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\),
The solution \(X^{t,x}= (X_{s}^{t,x})_{s\leq T}\) exists and is unique under Assumption 2.1 (cf. Karatzas and Shreve [22], p.289). We recall a well-known result associated to integrability of the solution. For any fixed \((t, x)\in[0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\), \(p\geq2\), it holds that, P-a.s.,
where the constant C only depends on the Lipschitz coefficient and the bound of σ.
For integer \(n\geq1\), we first present the following Borelian function as the terminal coefficient of the n-dimensional BSDE that we are considering:
which satisfies the following.
Assumption 2.2
The function \(g^{i}\), \(i=1,2,\ldots,n\), is of polynomial growth with respect to x, i.e., there exist a constant \(C_{g}\) and \(\gamma\geq0\) such that
Now, we consider Borelian functions \(H_{i}\), \(i=1,2,\ldots,n\), from \([0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\times \mathbf{R}^{n}\times \mathbf{R}^{nm}\) into R as follows:
which satisfy the following hypothesis.
Assumption 2.3
-
(i)
For each \((t,x,y^{1},\ldots,y^{n},z^{1},\ldots,z^{n})\in[0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\times \mathbf{R}^{n}\times \mathbf{R}^{nm}\), there exist constants \(C_{2}\), \(C_{h}\) and \(\gamma>0\) such that, for each \(i=1,2,\ldots,n\),
$$ \bigl\vert H_{i}\bigl(t,x,y^{1}, \ldots,y^{n},z^{1},\ldots,z^{n}\bigr)\bigr\vert \leq C_{2}\bigl(1+\vert x\vert \bigr)\bigl\vert z^{i} \bigr\vert + C_{h}\bigl(1+\vert x\vert ^{\gamma}+\bigl\vert y^{i}\bigr\vert \bigr) ; $$(2.4) -
(ii)
the mapping \((y^{1},\ldots, y^{n}, z^{1},\ldots,z^{n})\in \mathbf{R}^{n}\times \mathbf{R}^{nm}\longmapsto H_{i}(t,x,y^{1},\ldots, y^{n},z^{1},\ldots,z^{n}) \in \mathbf{R}\) is continuous for any fixed \((t,x) \in[0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\).
For a fixed constant \(a\in \mathbf{R}^{m}\), and \(i=1,2,\ldots,n\), let us consider the following BSDE:
From Assumptions 2.2 and 2.3, we know that this is a multiple dimensional coupled BSDEs system under Markovian framework with unbounded terminal value.
3 Existence of solutions for the multiple dimensional coupled BSDEs system
In this section, we provide an existence result of BSDEs (2.5) when \(n=2\) as an example. Actually, the case for \(n>2\) can be dealt with in the same way without any difficulties.
3.1 Measure domination
Before we state our main theorem, let us first recall a result related to measure domination.
Definition 3.1
(\(L^{q}\)-domination condition)
Let \(q\in(1,\infty)\) be fixed. For given \(t_{1}\in[0,T]\), a family of probability measures \(\{\nu_{1}(s,dx), s\in[t_{1}, T]\}\) defined on \(\mathbf{R}^{m}\) is said to be \(L^{q}\)- dominated by another family of probability measures \(\{\nu_{0}(s,dx), s\in[t_{1}, T]\}\) if for any \(\delta\in(0, T-t_{1}]\), there exists an application \(\phi^{\delta}_{t_{1}}: [t_{1}+\delta, T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m} \rightarrow \mathbf{R}^{+}\) such that:
-
(i)
\(\nu_{1}(s, dx)\,ds= \phi^{\delta}_{t_{1}}(s, x)\nu_{0}(s, dx)\,ds\) on \([t_{1}+\delta, T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\).
-
(ii)
\(\forall k\geq1\), \(\phi^{\delta}_{t_{1}}(s,x) \in L^{q}([t_{1}+\delta, T]\times[-k, k]^{m}; \nu_{0}(s, dx)\,ds)\).
Lemma 3.1
Let \(a\in \mathbf{R}^{m}\), \((t,x)\in[0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\), \(s\in(t,T]\) and \(\mu(t,x;s,dy)\) the law of \(X^{t,x}_{s}\), i.e.,
Under Assumption 2.1 on σ, for any \(q\in(1,\infty )\), the family of laws \(\{\mu(t,x;s,dy), s\in[t,T]\}\) is \(L^{q}\)-dominated by \(\{\mu(0,a;s,dy), s\in[t,T]\}\) for fixed \(a\in \mathbf{R}^{m}\).
Proof
See [21], Lemma 4.3 and Corollary 4.4, pp.14-15. □
3.2 High-dimensional coupled BSDEs system
Our main result in this section is the following theorem.
Theorem 3.1
Let \(a\in \mathbf{R}^{m}\) be fixed. Then under Assumptions 2.1, 2.2 and 2.3, there exist two pairs of \(\mathcal {P}\)-measurable processes \((Y^{i}, Z^{i})\) with values in \(\mathbf{R}^{1+m}\), \(i=1,2\), and two deterministic functions \(\varsigma^{i}(t,x)\) which are of polynomial growth, i.e., \(|\varsigma^{i}(t,x)|\leq C(1+|x|^{\gamma })\) with \(\gamma\geq0\), \(i=1,2\), such that
The result holds true as well for the case \(i>2\) following the same way.
Proof
The structure of this proof is as follows. We first use the mollify technique on the generator \(H_{i}\) to construct a sequence of BSDEs with generators which are Lipschitz continuous. Then, we provide uniform estimates of the solutions as well as the convergence property. Finally, we verify that the limits of the sequences are exactly the solutions for BSDE (3.1).
Step 1. Approximation.
Let ξ be an element of \(C^{\infty}(\mathbf{R}^{2+2m}, \mathbf{R})\) with compact support and satisfy
For \((t,x,y^{1},y^{2},z^{1},z^{2})\in[0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\times \mathbf{R}^{2+2m}\), we set
where the truncation function \(\varphi_{n}(x)=((x_{j}\vee(-n))\wedge n)_{j=1,2,\ldots,m}\) for \(x=(x_{j})_{j=1,2,\ldots,m}\in \mathbf{R}^{m}\). We next define \(\psi\in C^{\infty}(\mathbf{R}^{2+2m},\mathbf{R})\) by
Then we define the measurable function sequence \((H_{1n})_{n\geq 1}\) as follows: \(\forall(t,x,y^{1},y^{2},z^{1},z^{2})\in[0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\times \mathbf{R}^{2+2m}\),
We have the following properties:
The construction of the approximating sequence \((H_{2}^{n})_{n\geq1}\) is carried out in the same way.
For each \(n\geq1\) and \((t,x)\in[0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\), since \(H_{1n}\) and \(H_{2n}\) are uniformly Lipschitz w.r.t. \((y^{1},y^{2},z^{1},z^{2})\), by the result of Pardoux-Peng (see [2]), we know that there exist two pairs of processes \((Y^{in;(t,x)}, Z^{in;(t,x)})\in\mathcal {S}_{t,T}^{2}(\mathbf{R})\times\mathcal{H}_{t,T}^{2}(\mathbf{R}^{m})\), \(i=1,2\), which satisfy, for \(s\in[t,T]\),
Meanwhile, properties (3.2)(a), (c) and the result of El-Karoui et al. (ref. [8]) yield that there exist two sequences of deterministic measurable applications \(\varsigma ^{1n}\ (\mbox{resp. } \varsigma^{2n}): [0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m} \rightarrow \mathbf{R}\) and \(\mathfrak{z}^{1n}\ (\mbox{resp. } \mathfrak{z}^{2n}): [0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\rightarrow \mathbf{R}^{m}\) such that for any \(s\in[t,T]\),
and
Besides, we have the following deterministic expression: for \(i=1,2\) and \(n\geq1\),
where
Step 2. Uniform integrability of \((Y^{1n;(t,x)}, Z^{1n;(t,x)})_{n\geq1}\) for fixed \((t,x)\in [0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\).
For each \(n\geq1\), let us first consider the following BSDE:
For any \(x\in \mathbf{R}^{m}\) and \(n\geq1\), the mapping \((y^{1},z^{1})\in \mathbf{R}\times \mathbf{R}^{m} \mapsto C_{2}(1+|\varphi_{n} (X_{r}^{t,x})|)|z^{1}| +C_{h}(1+|\varphi _{n}(X_{r}^{t,x})|^{\gamma}+ |y^{1}|)\) is Lipschitz continuous; therefore, the solution \((\bar{Y}^{1n}, \bar{Z}^{1n}) \in\mathcal{S}_{t,T}^{2}(\mathbf{R})\times\mathcal{H}_{t,T}^{2}(\mathbf{R}^{m})\) exists and is unique. Moreover, it follows from the result of El-Karoui et al. (see [8]) that \(\bar{Y}^{1n}\) can be characterized through a deterministic measurable function \(\bar{\varsigma}^{1n}: [0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m} \rightarrow \mathbf{R}\), that is, for any \(s\in[t,T]\),
Next let us consider the process
which is, thanks to Girsanov’s theorem, a Brownian motion under the probability \(\mathbf{P}^{n}\) on \((\Omega, \mathcal{F})\) whose density with respect to P is \(\mathcal{E}_{T}:=\mathcal{E}_{T}(\int_{0}^{T} C_{2}(1+|\varphi _{n}(X_{s}^{t,x})|)\operatorname{sign}(\bar{Z}_{s}^{1n}) 1_{[t,T]}(s)\,dB_{s})\), where for any \(z=(z^{i})_{i=1,\ldots,d}\in \mathbf{R}^{m}\), \(\mbox{sign}(z)=(1_{[|z^{i}|\neq0]}\frac{z^{i}}{|z^{i}|})_{i=1,\ldots,d}\) and \(\mathcal{E}_{t}(\cdot)\) is defined by
for any \((\mathcal{F}_{t}, \mathbf{P})\)-continuous local martingale \(M=(M_{t})_{t\leq T}\). Then (3.6) becomes
Applying Itô-Meyer’s formula to \((e^{C_{h} t}\bar{Y}_{t}^{1n})^{+}\), \(t\leq T\), we know
where \(L_{t}^{0}\) is the local time of the continuous semimartingale \(e^{C_{h} t}\bar{Y}_{t}^{1n}\) at time 0 which is an increasing process. Therefore, the term \(\int_{t}^{T}\,dL_{s}^{0}\) is positive. Considering (3.7), we have
where \(\mathbf{E}^{n}\) is the expectation under the probability \(\mathbf{P}^{n}\). Taking the expectation on both sides under the probability \(\mathbf{P}^{n}\) and taking account of \(\bar{\varsigma}^{1n}\) is deterministic and \(f^{+}\leq|f|\) for any integrable function f, we obtain
Since \(g^{1}\) is of polynomial growth, and \(e^{-C_{h}t}\leq1\) for \(t\in [0,T]\), we infer that, \(\forall(t,x)\in[0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\),
where the constant C depends only on T, \(C_{h}\) and \(C_{g}\). Next, by a result of Haussmann ([23], p.14, see also [21], Lemma 3.1), there exist some \(p_{0}\in(1,2)\) and a constant C which is independent of n such that \(\mathbf{E}[|\mathcal{E}_{T}|^{p_{0}}]\leq C\) uniformly. As a result of Young’s inequality and estimate (2.3), we have
which yields
Next, by the comparison theorem of BSDEs and property (3.2)(b), we actually have, for any \(s\in[t,T]\),
and by choosing \(s=t\), we get that \(\varsigma^{1n}(t,x)\leq C(1+|x|^{\lambda})\), \((t,x)\in[0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\). In a similar way, we can also show that for any \((t,x)\in[0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\), \(\varsigma ^{1n}(t,x)\geq-C(1+|x|^{\lambda})\). As a conclusion, \(\varsigma^{1n}\) is of polynomial growth on \((t,x)\) uniformly in n, i.e., there exist a constant C, which is independent of n, and \(\lambda >2\) such that
Combining (3.11) and (2.3), we deduce that, for any \(\alpha>1\), \(i=1,2\),
On the other hand, by applying Itô’s formula to \((Y^{in;(t,x)})^{2}\) and considering the uniform estimate (3.12), we can infer in a regular way that, for any \(t\in[0,T]\), \(i=1,2\),
Step 3. For fixed \(a\in \mathbf{R}^{m}\), there exists a subsequence of \(((Y_{s}^{1n;(0,a)},Z_{s}^{1n;(0,a)})_{0\leq s\leq T})_{n\geq1}\) which converges in space \(\mathcal{S}_{T}^{2}(\mathbf{R})\times\mathcal{H}_{T}^{2}(\mathbf{R}^{m})\) respectively to \((Y^{1}_{s}, Z^{1}_{s})_{0\leq s\leq T}\), a solution of BSDE (3.1). Let us recall expression (3.5) for case \(i=1\) and apply property (3.2)(b) combined with the uniform estimates (3.12), (3.13), (2.3) and Young’s inequality to show that, for \(1< q<2\),
Therefore, there exists a subsequence \(\{n_{k}\}\) (for notation simplification, we still denote it by \(\{n\}\)) and a \(\mathcal{B}([0, T])\otimes\mathcal{B}(\mathbf{R}^{m})\)-measurable deterministic function \(F_{1}(s,y)\) such that
Next we aim to prove that \((\varsigma^{1n}(t,x))_{n\geq1}\) is a Cauchy sequence for each \((t,x)\in[0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\). Now let \((t,x)\) be fixed, \(\eta>0\), k, n and \(m\geq1\) be integers. From (3.5), we have
where on the right-hand side, noticing (3.14), we obtain
At the same time, Lemma 3.1 associated with the \(\mathcal {L}^{\frac{q}{q-1}}\)-domination property implies
Since \(\phi_{t,x,a}(s,\eta) \in\mathcal{L}^{\frac{q}{q-1}}([t+\eta, T]\times[-k, k]^{m} ; \mu(0,a; s, d\eta)\,ds)\), for \(k\geq1\), it follows from (3.15) that for each \((t,x)\in[0, T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\), we have
Finally,
Therefore, for each \((t,x)\in[0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\), \((\varsigma ^{1n}(t,x))_{n\geq1}\) is a Cauchy sequence, and then there exists a Borelian application \(\varsigma^{1}\) on \([0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\) such that for each \((t,x)\in[0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\), \(\lim_{n\rightarrow \infty}\varsigma^{1n}(t,x)=\varsigma^{1}(t,x)\), which indicates that for \(t\in[0,T]\), \(\lim_{n\rightarrow\infty} Y_{t}^{1n;(0,a)}(\omega )=\varsigma^{1}(t,X_{t}^{0,a})\), P-a.s. Taking account of (3.12) and Lebesgue’s dominated convergence theorem, we obtain that the sequence \(((Y_{t}^{1n;(0,a)})_{0\leq t\leq T})_{n\geq1}\) converges to \(Y^{1}=(\varsigma^{1}(t, X_{t}^{0,a}))_{0\leq t\leq T}\) in \(\mathcal{L}^{p}([0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m})\) for any \(p\geq1\), that is,
Next, we will show that for any \(p>1\), \(Z^{1n;(0,a)}=((\mathfrak {z}^{1n}(t,X_{t}^{0,a}))_{0\leq t\leq T})_{n\geq1}\) has a limit in \(\mathcal{H}_{T}^{2}(\mathbf{R}^{m})\). Besides, \((Y^{1n;(0,a)})_{n\geq1}\) is convergent in \(\mathcal{S}_{T}^{2}(\mathbf{R})\) as well. We now focus on the first claim. For \(n,m \geq1\) and \(0 \leq t\leq T\), using Itô’s formula with \((Y_{t}^{1n}-Y_{t}^{1m})^{2}\) (we omit the subscript \((0,a)\) for convenience) and considering (3.2)(b), we get
Since for any \(x,y,z\in \mathbf{R}\), \(|xyz|\leq\frac{1}{a}|x|^{a}+\frac {1}{b}|y|^{b}+\frac{1}{c}|z|^{c}\) with \(\frac{1}{a}+\frac{1}{b}+\frac {1}{c}=1\), then for any \(\varepsilon>0\) we have
Taking now \(t=0\) in (3.17), expectation on both sides and the limit w.r.t. n and m, we deduce that
due to (3.13), (2.3) and the convergence of (3.16). As ε is arbitrary, then the sequence \((Z^{1n})_{n\geq1}\) is convergent in \(\mathcal{H}_{T}^{2}\) to a process \(Z^{1}\).
Now, returning to inequality (3.17), taking the supremum over \([0,T]\) and using BDG’s inequality, we obtain that
which implies that
since ε is arbitrary and (3.18). Thus, the sequence of \((Y^{1n})_{n\geq1}\) converges to \(Y^{1}\) in \(\mathcal{S}_{T}^{2}\), which is a continuous process.
Finally, repeating the procedure for player \(i=2\), we have also the convergence of \((Z^{2n})_{n\geq1}\) (resp. \((Y^{2n})_{n\geq1}\)) in \(\mathcal{H}_{T}^{2}\) (resp. \(\mathcal{S}_{T}^{2}\)) to \(Z^{2}\) (resp. \(Y^{2}=\varsigma^{2}(., X^{0,x})\)).
Step 4. The limit process \((Y_{t}^{i},Z_{t}^{i})_{0\leq t\leq T}\), \(i=1,2\), is the solution of BSDE (3.1).
Indeed, we need to show that (for case \(i=1\))
For \(k\geq1\), we have
The sequence \(I_{1}^{n}\), \(n\geq1\), converges to 0. On the one hand, for \(n\geq1\), property (3.2)(b) in Step 1 implies that
On the other hand, considering property (3.2)(d), we obtain that
as \(n\rightarrow\infty\). Thanks to Lebesgue’s dominated convergence theorem, the sequence \(I_{1}^{n}\) of (3.19) converges to 0 in \(\mathcal {H}_{T}^{1}\).
The sequence \(I_{2}^{n}\) in (3.19) is bounded by \(\frac {C}{k^{2(q-1)/q}}\) with \(q\in(1,2)\). Actually, from property (3.2)(b) and Markov’s inequality, for \(q\in(1,2)\), we get
The last inequality is a straightforward result of estimates (2.3), (3.12) and (3.13).
The third sequence \(I_{3}^{n}\), \(n\geq1\), in (3.19) also converges to 0, at least for a subsequence. Actually, since the sequence \((Z^{1n})_{n\geq1}\) converges to \(Z^{1}\) in \(\mathcal{H}_{T}^{2}\), then there exists a subsequence \((Z^{1n_{k}})_{k\geq1}\) such that it converges to \(Z^{1}\), \(dt\otimes d\mathbf{P}\)-a.e.; and furthermore, \(\sup_{k\geq1}|Z_{t}^{1n_{k}}(\omega)|\in\mathcal{H}_{T}^{2}\). On the other hand, \((Y^{1n_{k}})_{k\geq1}\) converges to \(Y^{1}\), \(dt\otimes d\mathbf{P}\)-a.e. Thus, by the continuity of function \(H_{1}(t,x,y^{1},y^{2},z^{1},z^{2})\) w.r.t. \((y^{1},y^{2},z^{1},z^{2})\), we obtain that
In addition, considering that
which follows from (3.14). Finally, by the dominated convergence theorem, one can get that
which yields the convergence of \(I_{3}^{n}\) in (3.19) to 0.
It follows that the sequence \((H_{1n}(t,X_{t}^{0,a},Y_{t}^{1n},Y_{t}^{2n},Z_{t}^{1n},Z_{t}^{2n})_{0\leq t\leq T})_{n\geq1}\) converges to \((H_{1}(t, X_{t}^{0,a},Y_{t}^{1},Y_{t}^{2},Z_{t}^{1},Z_{t}^{2}))_{0\leq t\leq T}\) in \(\mathcal{L}^{1}([0,T]\times\Omega, dt\otimes d\mathbf{P})\) and then \(F_{1}(t,X_{t}^{0,a})=H_{1}(t,X_{t}^{0,a},Y_{t}^{1},Y_{t}^{2}, Z_{t}^{1},Z_{t}^{2})\), \(dt\otimes d\mathbf{P}\)-a.e. In the same way, we have \(F_{2}(t, X_{t}^{0,x})=H_{2}(t,X_{t}^{0,a},Y_{t}^{1},Y_{t}^{2},Z_{t}^{1},Z_{t}^{2})\), \(dt\otimes d\mathbf{P}\)-a.e. Thus, the processes \((Y^{i}, Z^{i})\), \(i=1,2\), are the solutions of the backward equation (3.1). □
4 Generalizations
As we can see from Assumption 2.3(i), this model deals with BSDE (2.5) with stochastic linear growth generators. However, when x takes value of \(X^{0,a}\), the coefficient of the component \(y^{i}\) in (2.4) is deterministic. Therefore, one possible generalization is to improve this model by considering the following assumption instead of Assumption 2.3.
Assumption 4.1
-
(i)
For each \((t,x,y^{1},\ldots,y^{n},z^{1},\ldots,z^{n})\in[0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\times \mathbf{R}^{n}\times \mathbf{R}^{nm}\), there exist a constant C and \(0<\gamma<2\) such that, for each \(i=1,2,\ldots,n\),
$$ \bigl\vert H_{i}\bigl(t,x,y^{1},\ldots,y^{n},z^{1}, \ldots,z^{n}\bigr)\bigr\vert \leq C\bigl(1+\vert x\vert \bigr) \bigl\vert z^{i}\bigr\vert + C\bigl(1+|x|^{\gamma }\bigr)\bigl\vert y^{i}\bigr\vert ; $$(4.1) -
(ii)
the mapping \((y^{1},\ldots, y^{n}, z^{1},\ldots,z^{n})\in \mathbf{R}^{n}\times \mathbf{R}^{nm}\longmapsto H_{i}(t,x,y^{1},\ldots, y^{n},z^{1},\ldots,z^{n}) \in \mathbf{R}\) is continuous for any fixed \((t,x) \in[0,T]\times \mathbf{R}^{m}\).
Then we will obtain a similar conclusion below. However, notice that we can only conveniently deal with the case when γ is strictly smaller than 2.
Theorem 4.1
Let \(a\in \mathbf{R}^{m}\) be fixed. Then, under Assumptions 2.1, 2.2 and 4.1, there exist two pairs of \(\mathcal {P}\)-measurable processes \((Y^{i}, Z^{i})\) with values in \(\mathbf{R}^{1+m}\), \(i=1,2\), and two deterministic functions \(\varsigma^{i}(t,x)\) with the growth property as follows, \(|\varsigma^{i}(t,x)|\leq e^{C(1+|x|^{\gamma })}\) with \(0<\gamma<2 \), \(i=1,2\), such that equations (3.1) hold true.
Sketch of the proof
One can follow the same method of the proof of Theorem 3.1. We only point out here some difference in Step 2 related to the growth property of the deterministic function \(\varsigma^{1n}\).
In Step 2, we consider the following BSDE sequence:
After changing probability following the same line as (3.8), we obtain
Considering \(\bar{Y}_{s}^{1n}=\bar{\varsigma}^{1n}(s, X_{s}^{t,x})\) for the deterministic function \(\bar{\varsigma}^{1n}\), we obviously have
This inequality is obtained from the integrability of \(\mathcal{E}_{T}\) in \(\mathcal{L}^{p_{0}}\) for some \(p_{0}\in(1,2)\) and the fact that \((1+|x|)< e^{1+|x|}\) for any x. Therefore, by comparison theorem, we know \(\varsigma^{1n}(t,x)\leq e^{C(1+|x|^{\gamma})}\). In a similar way, we can also show that \(\varsigma^{1n}(t,x)\geq e^{-C(1+|x|^{\gamma})}\).
Combining this growth property and the fact that \(Y_{s}^{1n:(t,x)}=\varsigma^{1n}(s, X_{s}^{t,x})\), we conclude that, for any \(\alpha>1\) and \(0<\gamma<2\),
since
is true only for positive γ strictly smaller than 2. When γ touches 2 or bigger than 2, then estimate (4.4) is not necessarily true for arbitrary \(T>0\). In this case, (4.4) may explode, and this is the reason why we only consider \(\gamma\in(0,2)\) in Assumption 4.1. However, for \(\gamma \geq2\), we can still expect that (4.4) holds true for T small enough.
The rest of the proof will have no practical difficulties, therefore, we omit it.
References
Bismut, J-M: Conjugate convex functions in optimal stochastic control. J. Math. Anal. Appl. 44(2), 384-404 (1973)
Pardoux, E, Peng, S: Adapted solution of a backward stochastic differential equation. Syst. Control Lett. 14(1), 55-61 (1990)
Duffie, D, Epstein, LG: Stochastic differential utility. Econometrica 60, 353-394 (1992)
El-Karoui, N, Mazliak, L: Backward Stochastic Differential Equations. Pitman Research Notes in Mathematics Series, vol. 364. Longman, Harlow (1997)
El-Karoui, N, Hamadene, S, Matoussi, A: Backward stochastic differential equations and applications In: Carmona, R (ed.) Indifference Pricing : Theory and Applications, pp. 267-320. Princeton University Press, Princeton (2008)
Carmona, R: Indifference Pricing: Theory and Applications. Princeton University Press, Princeton (2009)
Yong, J, Zhou, XY: Stochastic Controls: Hamiltonian Systems and HJB Equations, vol. 43. Springer, New York (1999)
El-Karoui, N, Peng, S, Quenez, MC: Backward stochastic differential equations in finance. Math. Finance 7(1), 1-71 (1997)
Peng, S: Backward stochastic differential equation, nonlinear expectation and their applications. In: Proceedings of the International Congress of Mathematicians, pp. 393-432 (2011)
Mao, X: Adapted solutions of backward stochastic differential equations with non-Lipschitz coefficients. Stoch. Process. Appl. 58(2), 281-292 (1995)
Hamadène, S: Equations différentielles stochastiques rétrogrades: le cas localement lipschitzien. Ann. Inst. Henri Poincaré B, Probab. Stat. 32(5), 645-659 (1996)
Lepeltier, J-P, San Martin, J: Backward stochastic differential equations with continuous coefficient. Stat. Probab. Lett. 32(4), 425-430 (1997)
Jia, G: A uniqueness theorem for the solution of backward stochastic differential equations. C. R. Math. 346(7), 439-444 (2008)
Briand, P, Carmona, R: BSDEs with polynomial growth generators. Int. J. Stoch. Anal. 13(3), 207-238 (2000)
Briand, P, Lepeltier, RJ-P, San Martin, J, et al.: One-dimensional backward stochastic differential equations whose coefficient is monotonic in y and non-Lipschitz in z. Bernoulli 13(1), 80-91 (2007)
Kobylanski, M: Backward stochastic differential equations and partial differential equations with quadratic growth. Ann. Probab. 28(2), 558-602 (2000)
Briand, P, Hu, Y: BSDE with quadratic growth and unbounded terminal value. Probab. Theory Relat. Fields 136(4), 604-618 (2006)
Hamadène, S, Lepeltier, J-P, Peng, S: BSDEs with Continuous Coefficients and Stochastic Differential Games. Pitman Research Notes in Mathematics Series, pp. 115-128, (1997)
Bahlali, K: Backward stochastic differential equations with locally Lipschitz coefficient. C. R. Acad. Sci., Ser. 1 Math. 333(5), 481-486 (2001)
Bahlali, K: Existence and uniqueness of solutions for BSDEs with locally Lipschitz coefficient. Electron. Commun. Probab. 7(17), 169-179 (2002)
Hamadène, S, Mu, R: Existence of Nash equilibrium points for Markovian non-zero-sum stochastic differential games with unbounded coefficients. Stoch. Int. J. Probab. Stoch. Process. 87 85-111 (2015). doi:10.1080/17442508.2014.915973
Karatzas, I, Shreve, SE: Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus, 2nd edn. Springer, New York (1991)
Haussmann, UG: A Stochastic Maximum Principle for Optimal Control of Diffusions. Wiley, New York (1986)
Acknowledgements
The authors thank the anonymous reviewers for their useful comments and suggestions. The first author was supported in part by the Natural Science Foundation for Young Scientists of Jiangsu Province, P.R. China (No. BK20140299). The second author was supported in part by National Natural Science Foundation of China (11221061 and 61174092), 111 project (B12023), the National Natural Science Fund for Distinguished Young Scholars of China (11125102) and the Chang Jiang Scholar Program of Chinese Education Ministry.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
Competing interests
The authors declare that they have no competing interests.
Authors’ contributions
RM carried out the model formulation, the proof and the edit work. ZW reviewed and edited the manuscript. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.
Rights and permissions
Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.
About this article
Cite this article
Mu, R., Wu, Z. One kind of multiple dimensional Markovian BSDEs with stochastic linear growth generators. Adv Differ Equ 2015, 265 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1186/s13662-015-0607-3
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s13662-015-0607-3