- Research
- Open Access
- Published:
An asymmetric information non-zero sum differential game of mean-field backward stochastic differential equation with applications
Advances in Difference Equations volume 2019, Article number: 236 (2019)
Abstract
This paper is concerned with a kind of non-zero sum differential game driven by mean-field backward stochastic differential equation (MF-BSDE) with asymmetric information, whose novel feature is that both the state equation and the cost functional are of mean-field type. A necessary condition and a sufficient condition for Nash equilibrium point of the above problem are established. As applications, a mean-field linear-quadratic (MF-LQ) problem and a financial problem are studied.
1 Introduction
Mean-field theory has been an active research field in recent years, which has attracted a lot of researchers to investigate this theory. Mean-field theory was independently proposed by Lasry and Lions [1] and Huang et al. [2], respectively. Since then, research on related topics and their applications has become popular among scholars. For instance, Bensoussan et al. [3] investigated the existence and uniqueness of equilibrium strategies of LQ mean-field games; Øksendal and Sulem [4] researched optimal control of predictive mean-field equation and applied the theoretical results to solve optimal portfolio and consumption rate problems; Wu and Liu [5] derived the maximum principle for mean-field zero-sum stochastic differential game with partial information and applied the results to study a portfolio game problem; Hafayed et al. [6] studied the mean-field stochastic control problem under partial information and derived a necessary condition and a sufficient condition for optimal control; Huang and Wang [7] investigated a partial information linear-quadratic-Gauss game of larger-population system and obtained the decentralized strategy and approximate Nash equilibrium by studying the related mean-field game. We emphasize that the systems introduced in [3,4,5,6,7] are governed by forward stochastic differential equations (SDEs).
Nonlinear BSDE was introduced by Pardoux and Peng [8]. From then on, the theory of BSDE has made a rapid development due to its wide applications. Shen and Jiang [9] proved the existence and uniqueness of BSDE driven by time-changed Lévy noise, where the generator is monotonic and general growth with respect to variable y, and Mu and Wu [10] provided an existence result of a coupled Markovian BSDE system. Hamadène and Lepeltier [11] discussed a stochastic zero-sum differential game of BSDE and obtained the existence of saddle point under the bounded case and Isaacs’ condition. Wang and Yu [12] established a necessary condition and a verification theorem for open-loop Nash equilibrium point of non-zero sum differential game of BSDE under partial information. Furthermore, Wang et al. [13] discussed asymmetric information LQ non-zero sum differential game of BSDE and gave the feedback Nash equilibrium points. See also Wang and Yu [14], Li and Yu [15] for more information.
In 2009, Buckdahn et al. [16] firstly introduced a new kind of BSDE by investigating a special mean-field problem, which is called MF-BSDE. Then, Ma and Liu [17] studied a partial information optimal control of infinite horizon MF-BSDE with delay, and a necessary condition and a sufficient condition for optimal control were derived; Li et al. [18] solved an LQ control problem of MF-BSDE, and the optimal control was represented by two Riccati-type equations and a mean-field SDE. Besides, Wu and Liu [19] studied an optimal control problem for mean-field zero-sum stochastic differential game under partial information. Recently, Lin et al. [20] discussed an open-loop LQ leader-follower of mean-field stochastic differential game and solved the corresponding optimal control problems for the follower and the leader; Du and Wu [21] considered a new kind of Stackelberg differential game of MF-BSDE, and they obtained the open-loop Stackelberg equilibrium, which admits a state feedback representation. What is more, Zhang [22] investigated an optimal control problem for terminal constraint mean-field SDE under partial information, which was solved by the backward separation method with a decomposition technique. To our best knowledge, the mean-field backward stochastic differential game has important applications in economic and financial fields, and the corresponding result is quite lacking in literature, then we highly desire to study such a topic. Note that the system in [17, 18] only contains one control process, [19] discussed the zero-sum game for a forward system, and [20, 21] investigated game problems under full information. Due to this, Problem (MFBNZ) is distinguished from the above literature.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. In Sect. 2, we introduce some basic notations and formulate the asymmetric information non-zero sum differential game of MF-BSDE. In Sect. 3, we establish a necessary condition and a sufficient condition for Nash equilibrium point of Problem (MFBNZ). In Sect. 4, we investigate the well-posedness of initial coupled mean-field forward and backward stochastic differential equation (MF-FBSDE), which plays an important role in Sects. 5 and 6. In Sect. 5, we use the theoretical results to study an MF-LQ problem with asymmetric information and give an explicit form of Nash equilibrium point. In Sect. 6, we put a financial problem into the framework of Problem (MFBNZ) and obtain a feedback optimal investment strategy. In Sect. 7, we give some concluding remarks.
2 Notations and problem formulation
Throughout this paper, we denote by \(\mathbb{R}^{k} \) the k-dimensional Euclidean space, by \(\mathbb{R}^{k\times l}\) the collection of \(k\times l\) matrices, by \(A^{\tau }\) the transpose of A, by \(\langle \cdot ,\cdot \rangle \) and \(|\cdot | \) the inner product and the norm in Euclidean space, respectively. Let \((\varOmega , \mathcal{F},\mathcal{F}_{t},P)\) be a complete filtered probability space with a natural filtration \(\{\mathcal{F}_{t},t\geq 0\}\) generated by an \(\mathcal{F}_{t}\)-adapted, l-dimensional standard Brownian motion \(\{W(t), t\geq 0\}\). Also, we denote by \(\mathcal{L}^{2}_{\mathcal{F}}(0,T; \mathbb{R}^{n})\) the space of all \(\mathbb{R}^{n}\)-valued, \(\mathcal{F}_{t}\)-adapted processes such that \(\mathbb{E}\int ^{T}_{0}|x(t)|^{2} \,dt< +\infty \), and by \(\mathcal{L} ^{2}_{\mathcal{F}}(\varOmega ,\mathcal{F}_{T},P;\mathbb{R}^{n})\) the space of all \(\mathbb{R}^{n}\)-valued, \(\mathcal{F}_{T}\)-measurable random variables such that \(\mathbb{E}|\xi |^{2} < +\infty \).
In this paper, we study a kind of asymmetric information non-zero sum differential game of MF-BSDE. We only consider the case of two players. Similarly, we can study the case of n players. Consider the MF-BSDE
where we adopt the notation \(v(\cdot )=(v_{1}(\cdot ), v_{2}(\cdot ))\) for simplicity; \(f:\varOmega \times [0,T]\times \mathbb{R}^{n} \times \mathbb{R}^{n \times l}\times \mathbb{R}^{n} \times \mathbb{R}^{n \times l}\times \mathbb{R}^{k_{1}}\times \mathbb{R}^{k_{2}} \longrightarrow \mathbb{R}^{n}\) is a given continuous function; \(\xi \in \mathcal{L} ^{2}_{\mathcal{F}}(\varOmega ,\mathcal{F}_{T},P;\mathbb{R}^{n})\); \(v_{1}(\cdot )\) and \(v_{2}(\cdot )\) are the control processes of Player 1 and Player 2, respectively. MF-BSDE (1) characters that the two players cooperate to reach a terminal goal ξ at T.
Let \(U_{i}\) \((i=1,2)\) be a nonempty convex subset of \(\mathbb{R}^{k _{i}}\), and \(\mathcal{F}^{i}_{t}\subseteq \mathcal{F}_{t}\) be a given sub-filtration which is the information available to Player i at time \(t \in [0,T]\). Introduce the admissible control set
which is called an open-loop admissible control set for Player i.
Hypothesis 1
The function f is continuously differentiable in \((y,z, \bar{y},\bar{z},v_{1},v_{2})\). Moreover, its partial derivatives \(f_{y},f_{z},f_{\bar{y}},f_{\bar{z}},f_{v_{1}},f_{v_{2}}\) are uniformly bounded.
Suppose that \(v_{1}(\cdot )\) and \(v_{2}(\cdot )\) are admissible controls and Hypothesis 1 holds. With the assumptions, MF-BSDE (1) has a unique solution \((y(\cdot ), z(\cdot ))\) \(\in \mathcal{L}_{\mathcal{F}}^{2}(0,T;\mathbb{R}^{n})\times \mathcal{L} _{\mathcal{F}}^{2}(0,T;\mathbb{R}^{n\times l})\) (see Buckdahn et al. [16]). Ensuring achievement of the goal ξ, the two players have their own benefits described by the cost functional
\((i=1,2)\), where \(l_{i}:\varOmega \times [0,T]\times \mathbb{R}^{n} \times \mathbb{R}^{n \times l}\times \mathbb{R}^{n} \times \mathbb{R} ^{n \times l}\times \mathbb{R}^{k_{1}}\times \mathbb{R}^{k_{2}} \rightarrow \mathbb{R}\) and \(\varPhi _{i}:\mathbb{R}^{n}\rightarrow \mathbb{R}\) are continuous, and \(l_{i}\) satisfies
for all \((v_{1}(\cdot ),v_{2}(\cdot ))\in \mathcal{U}_{1} \times \mathcal{U}_{2}\).
Hypothesis 2
\(l_{i}\) and \(\varPhi _{i}\) (\(i=1,2\)) are continuously differentiable with respect to \((y,z,\bar{y},\bar{z}, v_{1},v_{2})\) and y, respectively. Besides, there exists a constant C such that the partial derivatives \(l_{iy},l_{iz},l_{i\bar{y}},l_{i\bar{z}},l_{iv_{1}},l_{iv _{2}}\) \((i=1,2)\) are bounded by \(C(1+|y|+|z|+|\bar{y}|+|\bar{z}|+|v _{1}|+|v_{2}|)\).
Problem (MFBNZ)
Find a pair of \((u_{1}(\cdot ),u_{2}(\cdot ))\in \mathcal{U}_{1}\times \mathcal{U}_{2}\) such that
subject to state equation (1) and cost functional (2). We call the above problem a mean-field backward non-zero sum stochastic differential game with asymmetric information. If \((u_{1}(\cdot ),u _{2}(\cdot ))\) satisfies (3), we call it a Nash equilibrium point of Problem (MFBNZ).
3 Maximum principle
In this section, we will give a necessary condition and a sufficient condition for Nash equilibrium point of Problem (MFBNZ).
Define the Hamiltonian function \(H_{i}\): \(\varOmega \times [0,T]\times \mathbb{R}^{n}\times \mathbb{R}^{n\times l}\times \mathbb{R}^{n} \times \mathbb{R}^{n\times l}\times \mathbb{R}^{k_{1}}\times \mathbb{R}^{k_{2}}\times \mathbb{R}^{n} \rightarrow \mathbb{R} \) by \(H_{i}(t,y,z,\bar{y},\bar{z},v_{1},v_{2},p_{i})=\langle p_{i},-f(t,y,z, \bar{y},\bar{z},v_{1},v_{2})\rangle +l_{i}(t,y,z,\bar{y},\bar{z},v _{1},v_{2})\) \((i=1,2)\), where \(p_{i}(\cdot )\) satisfies
with \(H_{iy},H_{i\bar{y}},H_{iz}\), and \(H_{i\bar{z}}\) being the partial derivatives of \(H_{i}\) with respect to \(y,\bar{y},z\), and z̄, respectively.
3.1 The necessary condition
Assume that \((u_{1}(\cdot ),u_{2}(\cdot ))\) is a Nash equilibrium point of Problem (MFBNZ). For fixed \(u_{1}(\cdot )\), to minimize the aforementioned cost functional \(J_{2}(u_{1}(\cdot ),v_{2}(\cdot ))\), subject to state equation (1) over \(\mathcal{U}_{2}\) is a “non-Markovian” optimal control problem of MF-BSDE. Similarly, for the case corresponding to fixed \(u_{2}(\cdot )\). Using the method introduced in Peng [23], we can analyze the differential game problem. Here we only present the main result for saving space.
Theorem 3.1
Let Hypotheses 1–2 hold. If \((u_{1}(\cdot ),u_{2}(\cdot ))\) is a Nash equilibrium point of Problem (MFBNZ) and \((y(\cdot ),z(\cdot ))\) is the corresponding state trajectory, then we have
holds for any \((v_{1},v_{2})\in U_{1} \times U_{2} \), where \(p_{i}(\cdot )\) satisfies (4).
3.2 The sufficient condition
Now we weaken Hypothesis 2 to
Hypothesis 3
For each \((v_{1},v_{2})\in \mathcal{U}_{1}\times \mathcal{U}_{2}\), \(l_{i}\) and \(\varPhi _{i}\) (\(i=1,2\)) are differentiable with respect to \((y^{v},z^{v},\bar{y}^{v},\bar{z}^{v},v_{1},v_{2})\) and y, respectively; besides, \(l_{i}(t,y,z,\bar{y},\bar{z}, v_{1},v_{2}) \in \mathcal{L}_{\mathcal{F}}^{1}(0,T;\mathbb{R})\).
Theorem 3.2
Let Hypothesis 1 and Hypothesis 3 hold. Suppose that \(l_{i}\ (i=1,2)\) is continuously differentiable in \(v_{i}\). Assume that adjoint equation (4) is uniquely solvable. Suppose that \((u_{1}(\cdot ),u_{2}(\cdot )) \in \mathcal{U}_{1}\times \mathcal{U}_{2}\) is given such that \(l_{iy}(\mathcal{X}(\cdot ))\), \(l_{iz}(\mathcal{X}(\cdot ))\), \(l_{i\bar{y}}(\mathcal{X}(\cdot ))\), \(l_{i\bar{z}}(\mathcal{X}(\cdot ))\), \(l_{iv_{i}}(\mathcal{X}(\cdot ))\)\(\in \mathcal{L}_{\mathcal{F}} ^{2}(0,T)\) \((i=1,2)\), where
In addition, for any \((t,v_{i})\in [0,T] \times U_{i}\) \((i=1,2)\), \(l_{iv_{i}}(\cdot ,y(\cdot ),z(\cdot ),\mathbb{E}y(\cdot ),\mathbb{E}z( \cdot ),v_{i},u_{3-i}(\cdot )) \in \mathcal{L}^{1}(\varOmega , \mathcal{F},P)\). Assume that \(H_{i}(t,y,z,\mathbb{E}y,\mathbb{E}z,v _{i},u_{3-i}(t),p_{i}(t))\) \((i=1,2)\) and \(\varPhi _{i}(y)\) are convex in \((y,z,\bar{y},\bar{z},v_{i})\) and y, respectively. Assume that
What is more, assume that \(\mathbb{E}[H_{iv_{i}}(t,y(t),z(t), \mathbb{E}y(t),\mathbb{E}z(t),v_{i},u_{3-i}(t),p_{i}(t))|\mathcal{F} ^{i}_{t}]\) \((i=1,2)\) is continuous at \(v_{i}=u_{i}(t)\) for all \(t\in [0,T]\). Then \((u_{1}(\cdot ),u_{2}(\cdot ))\) is a Nash equilibrium point of Problem (MFBNZ).
Proof
For any \(v_{1}(\cdot ) \in \mathcal{U}_{1}\), we consider
where \((y(\cdot ),z(\cdot ),\mathbb{E}y(\cdot ),\mathbb{E}z(\cdot ))\) and \((y^{v_{1}}(\cdot ),z^{v_{1}}(\cdot ),\mathbb{E}y^{v_{1}}(\cdot ), \mathbb{E}z^{v_{1}}(\cdot ))\) are the state trajectories corresponding to \((u_{1}(\cdot ),u_{2}(\cdot ))\) and \((v_{1}(\cdot ),u_{2}(\cdot ))\), respectively.
Let
Then we have
The integration \(A_{1}\) is written as
Since \(\varPhi _{1}(y)\) is convex on y,
Applying Itô’s formula to \(\langle p_{1}(\cdot ),y(\cdot )-y^{v _{1}}(\cdot )\rangle \), we get
Then,
Combining (5) with (6), we have
Since \(H_{1}(t,y,z,\mathbb{E}y,\mathbb{E}z,v_{1},u_{2}(t),p_{1}(t))\) is convex in \((y,z,\bar{y},\bar{z},v_{1})\), then (7) becomes
Noticing that \(v_{1}\rightarrow \mathbb{E}[H_{1}(t,y(t),z(t), \mathbb{E}y(t),\mathbb{E}z(t),v_{1},u_{2}(t),p_{1}(t))|\mathcal{F} ^{1}_{t}]\) can be the minimum at \(v_{1}=u_{1}(t)\), we have \(J_{1}(u _{1}(t),u_{2}(t))\leq J_{1}(v_{1}(t),u_{2}(t))\) for any \(v_{1}( \cdot )\in \mathcal{U}_{1}\). Then it implies that
Similarly, we have \(J_{2}(u_{1}(t),u_{2}(t))= \min_{v_{2}(\cdot )\in \mathcal{U}_{2}}J_{2}(u_{1}(t),v_{2}(t))\).
Thus, we draw the desired conclusion. □
4 Mean-field FBSDE
In this section, we study the existence and uniqueness of solution to an initial coupled MF-FBSDE, which will be used in the rest of this paper.
Consider the MF-FBSDE
where \(\varPi (\cdot )=(\cdot ,x(\cdot ),y(\cdot ),z_{1}(\cdot ),z_{2}( \cdot ),\mathbb{E}{x}(\cdot ),\mathbb{E}{y}(\cdot ),\mathbb{E}{z}_{1}( \cdot ),\mathbb{E}{z}_{2}(\cdot ))\); \(x,y,z_{1},z_{2}\) take values in \(\mathbb{R}^{n}, \mathbb{R}^{m}, \mathbb{R}^{m \times d}\), and \(\mathbb{R}^{m \times d}\), respectively; \(f, \sigma _{1}, \sigma _{2}, g, \varPsi \) are functions with appropriate dimensions.
Let G be an \(m\times n\) full-rank matrix and use the notations
Definition 4.1
\((x,y,z_{1},z_{2}):\varOmega \times [0,T]\rightarrow \mathbb{R} ^{n}\times \mathbb{R}^{m} \times \mathbb{R}^{m \times d}\times \mathbb{R}^{m \times d}\) is called an adapted solution of (8) if \((x,y,z_{1},z_{2})\in \mathcal{L}_{\mathcal{F}}^{2}(0,T;\mathbb{R} ^{n}\times \mathbb{R}^{m} \times \mathbb{R}^{m \times d}\times \mathbb{R}^{m \times d})\) and satisfies (8).
Hypothesis 4
-
(1)
\(A(t,\lambda ,\breve{\lambda })\) is uniformly Lipschitz with respect to λ, λ̆, and for each \(\lambda , \breve{\lambda }\), \(A(t,\lambda ,\breve{\lambda })\) is in \(\mathcal{L}_{\mathcal{F}}^{2}(0,T)\); \(\varPsi (x)\) is uniformly Lipschitz with respect to x.
-
(2)
$$ \textstyle\begin{cases} \mathbb{E}\langle A(t,\lambda ,\breve{\lambda })-A(t,\bar{{\lambda }},\bar{ \breve{\lambda }}),\lambda -\bar{\lambda }\rangle\\ \quad \leq -\beta _{1}( \mathbb{E} \vert G\underline{x} \vert ^{2})-\beta _{2}(\mathbb{E} \vert G^{\tau } \underline{y} \vert ^{2}+ \mathbb{E} \vert G^{\tau }\underline{{z}_{1}} \vert ^{2}+ \mathbb{E} \vert G^{\tau }\underline{{z}_{2}} \vert ^{2}), \\ \mathbb{E}\langle G(\varPsi (y)-\varPsi (\bar{y})),y-\bar{y}\rangle \leq - \mu _{2}\mathbb{E} \vert G^{\tau }\underline{y} \vert ^{2} \end{cases} $$(9)
for all \(\lambda =(x,y,z_{1},z_{2})\), \(\bar{\lambda }=(\bar{x}, \bar{y},\bar{z}_{1},\bar{z}_{2})\), \(\breve{\lambda }=(\breve{x}, \breve{y},\breve{z}_{1},\breve{z}_{2})\), \(\bar{\breve{\lambda }}=(\bar{ \breve{x}},\bar{\breve{y}},\bar{\breve{z}}_{1},\bar{\breve{z}}_{2})\), \((\underline{x},\underline{y}, {\underline{z_{1}}}, {\underline{z_{2}}})=(x- \bar{x},y-\bar{y},z_{1}-\bar{z}_{1},z_{2}-\bar{z}_{2})\), where \(\beta _{1},\beta _{2},\mu _{2}\) are given non-negative constants with \(\beta _{1}+\beta _{2}>0, \beta _{1}+\mu _{2}>0\). What is more, we have \(\beta _{1}>0\) (respectively, \(\beta _{2}>0,\mu _{2}>0\)) when \(m>n\) (respectively, \(m< n\)).
Theorem 4.1
Assume that Hypothesis 4 holds. MF-FBSDE (8) admits a unique solution \((x,y,z_{1},z_{2})\).
Proof
Similar to Yu and Ji [24] and Bensoussan et al. [25], we can prove this result. We omit the details for saving space. □
5 An MF-LQ problem
This section focuses on solving an LQ case of Problem (MFBNZ). Applying Theorem 3.1 and Theorem 3.2, we obtain an explicit form of Nash equilibrium point by optimal filters and Riccati equations. For simplicity, here we only deal with the case of one-dimensional Brownian motion.
Consider the linear MF-BSDE
and the cost functional
\((i=1,2)\), where \(v(\cdot )=(v_{1}(\cdot ), v_{2}(\cdot ))\); \(A(\cdot ),C_{2}(\cdot ),\bar{A}(\cdot ), \bar{C}_{2}(\cdot ), B_{i}( \cdot )\) \((i = 1, 2)\) are deterministic, uniformly bounded functions; \(\xi \in \mathcal{L}^{2}_{\mathcal{F}}(\varOmega ,\mathcal{F}_{T},P; \mathbb{R})\); \(v_{1}(\cdot )\) and \(v_{2}(\cdot )\) are the control processes; \(\bar{N}_{i}(\cdot )\) \((i=1,2)\) is deterministic, non-negative, and uniformly bounded function; \(M_{i}(\cdot )\), \(N_{i}(\cdot )\), and \(\gamma _{i0}\) \((i = 1, 2)\) are deterministic, positive and uniformly bounded functions. Here, we require \(N_{i}( \cdot )\) and \(\gamma _{i0}\) \((i=1,2)\) to be positive, which guarantees \(m_{i}\neq 0\) \((i=1,2)\) and \(k_{3} \neq 0\) given by (13)–(14) and (42), respectively.
To what follows, we want to get an explicit form of Nash equilibrium point. Due to the fact that \(\mathcal{F}_{t}^{i}\) available to Player i \((i=1,2)\) is only an abstract sub-filtration of \(\mathcal{F}_{t}\), it is impossible to obtain a feedback Nash equilibrium point in general. So we mainly study three special information structures as follows: (1) \(\mathcal{F}^{1}_{t}=\mathcal{F}^{2}_{t}=\sigma \{W_{2}(s); 0\leq s \leq t\}=\mathcal{F}^{W_{2}}_{t}\), i.e., Player 1 and Player 2 have the same observation information; (2) \(\mathcal{F}^{1}_{t}=\sigma \{W_{1}(s),W _{2}(s); 0\leq s \leq t\}=\mathcal{F}_{t},\mathcal{F}^{2}_{t}= \mathcal{F}^{W_{2}}_{t}\), i.e., Player 1 has more information than Player 2; (3) \(\mathcal{F}^{1}_{t}=\sigma \{W_{1}(s); 0\leq s \leq t \}=\mathcal{F}^{W_{1}}_{t}, \mathcal{F}^{2}_{t}=\mathcal{F}^{W_{2}} _{t}\), i.e., Player 1 and Player 2 possess the mutually independent information.
According to Theorem 3.1 and Theorem 3.2, \((u_{1}(\cdot ),u_{2}(\cdot ))\) is a Nash equilibrium point of the MF-LQ problem if and only if
where \((y,z_{1},z_{2},p_{1},p_{2})\) satisfies
For the sake of simplicity, here we omit the time variable t in (12). Similar convention will be taken for the subsequent equations except for the initial or terminal conditions. In addition, we give Hypothesis 5 throughout Sect. 5.
Hypothesis 5
\(B_{1}^{2}(t)M_{1}^{-1}(t)=B_{2}^{2}(t)M_{2}^{-1}(t)\), and \(B_{i}^{2}(t)M_{i}^{-1}(t)\) \((i=1,2)\) is independent of the time variable t.
5.1 Symmetric information: \(\mathcal{F}^{1}_{t} = \mathcal{F}^{2}_{t} =\mathcal{F}^{W_{2}}_{t}\)
In this case, we denote \(\mathbb{E}[p_{1}(t)|\mathcal{F}^{1}_{t}]= \mathbb{E} [p_{1}(t)|\mathcal{F}^{W_{2}}_{t} ]=\hat{p}_{1}(t)\) and \(\mathbb{E}[p_{2}(t)|\mathcal{F}^{2}_{t}]= \mathbb{E} [p_{2}(t)| \mathcal{F}^{W_{2}}_{t} ]=\hat{p}_{2}(t)\).
To derive an explicit form of Nash equilibrium point, we first introduce two sets of ordinary differential equations (ODEs):
and
Since (13) and (14) are coupled with each other, it is difficult to prove their existence and uniqueness except for some special cases. For example,
Hypothesis 6
\(C_{2}(t)=-\bar{C}_{2}(t)\).
Lemma 5.1
Under Hypotheses 5–6, there exists a unique solution \((\lambda _{1},m_{1},n_{1},\lambda _{2}, m_{2},n _{2})\) to (13) and (14).
Proof
Noticing (13) and (14), we introduce
In what follows, we prove that (15) is uniquely solvable. Let \(m=m_{1}+m_{2}\). Under Hypothesis 5, we have
Obviously, (16) is a standard Riccati equation, so it admits a unique solution \(m(\cdot )\). Introduce two new ODEs:
where \(m(\cdot )\) is the solution to (16). It is easy to see that (17) and (18) have unique solutions \({\widetilde{m}} _{1}\) and \({\widetilde{m}}_{2}\), respectively. Besides, we check that \(m_{1}\) and \(m_{2}\) in (15) are the solutions to (17) and (18), respectively. According to the existence and uniqueness of solutions to (17) and (18), we have
which implies that (15) admits a unique solution \((m_{1},m_{2})\).
Similarly, we introduce
with Hypothesis 5, where \((m_{1},m_{2})\) is the solution to (15). Let \(\lambda =\lambda _{1}+\lambda _{2}\). Then we have
Similar to (16), we can prove that (21) has a unique solution \(\lambda (\cdot )\). Introduce two other ODEs:
where \(\lambda (\cdot )\) is the solution to (21). Similar to (15), (20) admits a unique solution \((\lambda _{1}, \lambda _{2})\) satisfying
Finally, we introduce
where \(\lambda _{i},m_{i}\) \((i=1,2)\) are the solutions to (20) and (15), respectively. Besides, similar to (20) and (15), we know that (22) is uniquely solvable. For simplicity, we let \(n=n_{1}+n_{2}\).
Based on the arguments above, we get that (13) and (14) have unique solutions \((\lambda _{1},m_{1},n_{1})\) and \((\lambda _{2}, m _{2},n_{2})\), respectively. □
In the following, we will use five steps to give the explicit form of Nash equilibrium point.
Step 1: The unexplicit form of Nash equilibrium point.
\((u_{1}(\cdot ),u_{2}(\cdot ))\) is the Nash equilibrium point of the MF-LQ problem if and only if it is uniquely determined by
where \((y,z_{1},z_{2},p_{1},p_{2})\) is the solution of
Noticing that since (23) contains the conditional expectation of \(p_{i}(\cdot )\) \((i=1,2)\) with respect to \(\mathcal{F}_{t}^{W_{2}}\), we call it a conditional MF-FBSDE.
Step 2: Filtering equation.
Since (23) contains \(\hat{p}_{i}(\cdot )\) \((i=1,2)\), we need to compute the optimal filter \((\hat{y},\hat{z} _{2},\hat{p}_{1},\hat{p}_{2})\) of \((y,z_{2},p_{1},p_{2})\) with respect to \(\mathcal{F}^{W_{2}}_{t}\). Applying Lemma 5.4 in Xiong [26], we have
Note that this filtering equation is different from the case introduced in Chap. 2 of Wang et al. [27], whose existence and uniqueness need to be proved below.
Step 3: Existence and uniqueness of ( 24 ).
Introduce a new MF-FBSDE
With the help of Hypothesis 5, it is easy to check that Hypothesis 4 holds. Then Theorem 4.1 implies that (25) is uniquely solvable.
Now we intend to prove that the existence and uniqueness of (25) are equivalent to those of (24). On the one hand, we prove that the solution of (24) is the solution of (25). In fact, the conclusion is easily drawn with the assumption
On the other hand, we prove that the solution of (25) is the solution of (24). Let \((Y,Z_{2},P)\) be a solution of (25), and set
It follows from the existence and uniqueness of mean-field stochastic differential equation that \(\hat{p}_{i}\) satisfies
In order to say \((Y,Z_{2},\hat{p}_{i})\) \((i=1,2)\) is a solution of (24), we only check
Letting \(\bar{P}=B_{1}^{2}M^{-1}_{1}\hat{p}_{1}+B_{2}^{2}M^{-1}_{2} \hat{p}_{2}\), we have
Fixing Y, we derive \(P=\bar{P}\), and then (27) holds indeed. Hence, the existence and uniqueness of (25) are equivalent to those of (24).
Step 4: Existence and uniqueness of ( 23 ).
Fixing \(\hat{p}_{1}\) and \(\hat{p}_{2}\) in (23), we can easily prove that (23) admits a unique solution \((y,z_{1},z_{2},p_{1},p_{2})\).
Step 5: The feedback Nash equilibrium point.
According to the first equation of (23) together with the terminal condition in (23), we set
Applying Itô’s formula to \(p_{1}\) in (28), we have
Putting (28) into the second equation of (23), and comparing the coefficients of (29) and (23), we get
Taking \(\mathbb{E} [\cdot |\mathcal{F}_{t}^{W_{2}} ]\) on both sides of (28) and (30), we have
Here we assume \(m_{1}\neq 0\). Substituting (30) into (31) and taking \(\mathbb{E} [\cdot |\mathcal{F}_{t}^{W_{2}} ]\) on both sides of (31), it becomes
From (34), we derive (13). Similarly, (14) is derived by applying Itô’s formula to \(p_{2}\).
To close this subsection, we give the explicit form of \(\hat{y}(t)\). Putting (30) into the first equation of (23) and taking \(\mathbb{E}[\cdot ]\), we have
with
where m, λ and \(n=n_{1}+n_{2}\) are represented by (16), (21), and (22), respectively. Solving (35), we get its unique solution
Set
Then the first equation of (24) is written as
whose unique solution is
where \(X_{s}=\exp \{\int^{s}_{t} [q_{3}(r)- \frac{1}{2}C^{2}_{2}(r) ]\,dr+\int^{s}_{t}C_{2}(r)\,dW _{2}(r) \}\).
Theorem 5.1
Under Hypotheses 5–6, the feedback Nash equilibrium point \((u_{1}(t),u_{2}(t))\) of the MF-LQ problem is uniquely denoted by
where \(\lambda _{i},m_{i},n_{i}\) \((i=1,2)\), \({\mathbb{E} y}\) and ŷ are given by (13), (14), (37), and (40), respectively.
5.2 Asymmetric information
Here we solve two asymmetric information structures introduced above. The corresponding derivation procedures are similar to those of Sect. 5.1, so we omit the nonessential details and only give the main results.
5.2.1 \(\mathcal{F}^{1}_{t}=\mathcal{F}_{t}\) and \(\mathcal{F}^{2}_{t}=\mathcal{F}^{W_{2}}_{t}\)
In this case, \(\mathbb{E}[p_{1}(t)|\mathcal{F}^{1}_{t}]=\mathbb{E}[p _{1}(t)|\mathcal{F}_{t}]=p_{1}(t)\), \(\mathbb{E}[p_{1}(t)|\mathcal{F} ^{2}_{t}]=\mathbb{E} [p_{1}(t)|\mathcal{F}^{W_{2}}_{t} ]= \hat{p}_{2}(t) \).
Theorem 5.2
Let Hypotheses 5–6 hold. Then the feedback Nash equilibrium point \((u_{1}(t),u_{2}(t))\) of the MF-LQ problem is uniquely determined by
where \(\lambda _{2}\), \(m_{2}\), \(n_{2}\), \({\mathbb{E}y}\), and ŷ are the unique solutions to (14), (37), and (40), respectively; \(k_{i}\) \((i=1,2,3,4)\) and y satisfy
and
with \(q_{1},q_{2},q_{3}\) are represented by (36) and (38), respectively, and
respectively.
Feedback Nash equilibrium point (41) shows that although Player 1 observes full information, the control strategy of Player 1 is heavily influenced by the information available to Player 2 via \({\mathbb{E}y}\) and ŷ. This is an interesting phenomenon.
5.2.2 \(\mathcal{F}^{1}_{t}=\mathcal{F}^{W_{1}}_{t} \) and \(\mathcal{F}^{2}_{t}=\mathcal{F}^{W_{2}}_{t}\)
Hypothesis 7
\(C_{2}=\bar{C}_{2}=0\).
Hypothesis 7 guarantees that the filtering equation of (12) with respect to \(\mathcal{F}_{t}^{W_{1}}\) is uniquely solvable.
Theorem 5.3
Assume that Hypothesis 5 and Hypothesis 7 hold. Then the MF-LQ problem has a unique Nash equilibrium point \((u_{1}(t),u_{2}(t))\) represented by
where \(\tilde{y}(t)=\mathbb{E} [y(t)|\mathcal{F}_{t}^{W_{1}} ]\), \(w_{i}\), \(\rho _{i}\) \((i=1,2,3)\) are given by
and
with \(d_{i},l_{i}\) \((i=1,2)\) satisfying
and
respectively; \({\mathbb{E}y}\), ỹ and ŷ are given by
with
respectively.
6 Application in a financial problem
In this section, we consider an investment problem in a financial market. With the help of Theorem 3.1 and Theorem 3.2, an explicit form of optimal investment strategy is obtained.
We begin with a typical setup for the financial market, in which a bond and two stocks are continuously traded, and their prices satisfy
where \(r(\cdot )\) is called the interest rate of the bond; \(\mu _{i}( \cdot ), {\sigma }_{i}(\cdot )\) \((i=1,2)\) are called the appreciation rate of return and volatility coefficient of the ith stock.
Hypothesis 8
The market coefficients \(r(\cdot )\), \(\mu _{i}(\cdot ),{\sigma } _{i}(\cdot )\) \((i=1,2)\) are deterministic and bounded processes. What is more, \({\sigma }_{i}^{-1}(\cdot )\) \((i=1,2)\) is also bounded.
Suppose that there are two investors cooperating to invest a bond and two stocks, whose decision cannot influence the prices in the financial market. Furthermore, we assume that Investor 1 only cares about the price of the first stock, i.e., \(\mathcal{F}_{t}^{1}= \sigma \{S_{1}(s); 0 \leq s\leq t\}=\mathcal{F}_{t}^{S_{1}}\); however, Investor 2 cares about the prices of these two stocks, i.e., \(\mathcal{F}_{t}^{2}=\sigma \{S_{1}(s),S_{2}(s); 0 \leq s\leq t \}=\mathcal{F}_{t}^{S_{1},S_{2}}\). Clearly, \(\mathcal{F}_{t}^{S_{1}}= \sigma \{W_{1}(s); 0 \leq s\leq t\}\) and \(\mathcal{F}_{t}^{S_{1},S _{2}}=\sigma \{W_{1}(s),W_{2}(s); 0 \leq s\leq t\}\).
Assume that these two investors want to obtain a terminal wealth ξ at T, which is an \(\mathcal{F}_{T}\)-measurable, non-negative, and square-integrable random variable. Meanwhile, both of them hope to minimize their own risks, described by \(J_{i}\) \((i=1,2)\). In detail, we denote by \(\pi _{i}(\cdot )\) the amount that the investors invest in the ith \((i=1,2)\) stock and by \(y(\cdot )\) the wealth of the two investors. Then, \(y(\cdot )\) is modeled by
where \(b_{i}(\cdot )=(\mu _{i}(\cdot )-r(\cdot ))\sigma _{i}^{-1}( \cdot )\) \((i=1,2)\); \(z_{i}(\cdot )=\pi _{i}(\cdot )\sigma _{i}(\cdot )\) \((i=1,2)\); \(v_{1}(\cdot )\) and \(v_{2}(\cdot )\) are certain economic factors, which can be interpreted as capital injection or withdrawal.
Define the associated performance functional for each investor as follows:
\((i=1,2)\), where \(BM_{i}(\cdot )\) is a deterministic benchmark; \(\varPhi _{i}\) \((i=1,2)\) is a positive constant. In the performance functional, the first term measures the variance of the wealth \(y(\cdot )\); the second term measures the difference between the economic factor \(v_{i}(\cdot )\) and benchmark \(BM_{i}(\cdot )\) \((i=1,2)\) decided by the two investors; the last term in the performance functional characterizes the initial wealth \(y(\cdot )\) at time 0.
Let U be a nonempty and convex subset of \(\mathbb{R}\). Define the admissible control set
Then the investment problem is stated as follows.
Problem (F)
Find a pair of \((u_{1},u_{2}) \in \mathcal{U}_{1}\times \mathcal{U}_{2}\) such that
subject to (43) and (44). If such a pair of \((u_{1},u _{2})\) exists, we call it an optimal investment strategy of Problem (F).
Clearly, Problem (F) can be regarded as a non-zero sum mean-field backward stochastic differential game with asymmetric information, which is a special case of Problem (MFBNZ).
Here, we point out that Problem (F) is different from the MF-LQ problem, due to two distinguishing features below: firstly, the generator of the first equation of (47) has an additional term \(b_{2}\check{z}_{2}\), which leads to a difficulty of proving the existence and uniqueness of solution to it; secondly, (44) contains the first terms of \(y(\cdot )\) and \(v_{i}(\cdot )\), and then Theorem 5.2 cannot be used to solve Problem (F).
We firstly study a special case that \(\mathcal{F}_{t}^{1}=\mathcal{F} _{t}^{2}=\mathcal{F}_{t}^{S_{1}}\), which plays an important role in solving the asymmetric information case.
6.1 Symmetric information: \(\mathcal{F}_{t}^{1}= \mathcal{F}_{t}^{2}=\mathcal{F}_{t}^{S_{1}}\)
Let \(\check{g}(\cdot )={\mathbb{E}} [g(\cdot )|\mathcal{F}_{t} ^{S_{1}} ]\). We have \(\mathbb{E}[p_{1}(t)|\mathcal{F}_{t}^{1}]= \mathbb{E} [p_{1}(t)|\mathcal{F}_{t}^{S_{1}} ]=\check{p} _{1}(t)\) and \(\mathbb{E}[p_{2}(t)|\mathcal{F}_{t}^{2}]=\mathbb{E} [p_{1}(t)|\mathcal{F}_{t}^{S_{1}} ]=\check{p}_{2}(t)\). In the following, we use four steps to solve this case.
Step 1: Optimal investment strategy.
The optimal investment strategy \((u_{1},u_{2})\) of Problem (F) has the form of
where \((y,z_{1},z_{2},p_{1},p_{2})\) satisfies
Taking \(\mathbb{E} [\cdot |\mathcal{F}_{t}^{S_{1}} ]\) on both sides of each equation of (46) yields
Step 2: Existence and uniqueness of ( 50 ).
Introduce
Similar to Lemma 5.1, we can prove that (48) and (49) are uniquely solvable. What is more, it follows from \(\varPhi _{1}>0\) that the solution \(\gamma _{1}(\cdot )<0\). For convenience, let \(\gamma =\gamma _{1}+\gamma _{2}\), \(\eta =\eta _{1}+\eta _{2}\).
Introduce an auxiliary MF-FBSDE
which is subject to an additional hypothesis as follows.
Hypothesis 9
\(1+\gamma _{1}^{-1}(t)b_{2}^{2}(t)\geq 0\).
According to Hypothesis 4, (50) has a unique solution \((\check{y}, \check{z}_{1}, \check{p}_{1}, \check{p}_{2})\).
Step 3: The equivalence between ( 47 ) and ( 50 ) with ( 45 ).
We first prove that the solution \((\check{y}, \check{z}_{1},\check{p}_{1},\check{p}_{2})\) of (50) satisfies (47). If \(u_{i}(t)=BM_{i}(t)-\check{p}_{i}(t)\) \((i=1,2)\), then (46) is uniquely solvable. Set
Applying Itô’s formula to \(p_{1}\) in (51), we get
Comparing (52) with the second equation of (46), we have
Putting (53) into (54) subject to (51), and taking \(\mathbb{E}[\cdot ]\) on both sides of (54), we arrive at
which implies (48). Similarly, applying Itô’s formula to \(p_{2}\) in (51), we derive (49).
In addition, taking \(\mathbb{E} [\cdot |\mathcal{F}_{t}^{S_{1}} ] \) on both sides of (51) and (53), we get
\((i=1,2)\). Putting (57) into (50), it is easy to see that \((\check{y}, \check{z}_{1},\check{z}_{2},\check{p}_{1},\check{p}_{2})\) solves (47).
Next, with \(u_{1}\) and \(u_{2}\) fixed, we prove that the solution \((\check{y}, \check{z}_{1},\check{z}_{2},\check{p}_{1},\check{p}_{2})\) of (47) is a solution of (50). Take \(u_{i}=BM_{i}- \check{p}_{i}\) \((i=1,2)\). Then \((y,z_{1},z_{2},p_{1},p_{2})\) is the unique solution to (46). Substituting \(\check{z}_{i}=-\gamma _{1}^{-1}b_{i}\check{p}_{1}\) and \(u_{i}=BM_{i}-\check{p}_{i}\) \((i=1,2)\) into (47), we arrive at (50), which implies that \((\check{y},\check{z}_{1},\check{p}_{1},\check{p}_{2})\) is a solution of (50).
Based on the analysis above, we know that the existence and uniqueness of (47) are equivalent to those of (50).
Step 4: The explicit form of optimal investment strategy.
Due to (56) and (57), the first equation of (47) is written as
where
Solving (58), we get
with
What is more, the expectation of \(\check{y}(t)\) represented by (60) is
Theorem 6.1
Under Hypotheses 8–9, the optimal investment strategy of Problem (F) is denoted by
where \(\gamma _{i}\), \(\eta _{i}\) \((i=1,2)\) and y̌ are given by (48), (49), and (60), respectively.
6.2 Asymmetric information: \(\mathcal{F}_{t}^{1}= \mathcal{F}_{t}^{S_{1}}, \mathcal{F}_{t}^{2}=\mathcal{F}_{t}^{S_{1},S _{2}}\)
In this case, we have \(\mathbb{E}[p_{1}(t)|\mathcal{F}_{t}^{1}]= \mathbb{E} [p_{1}(t)|\mathcal{F}_{t}^{S_{1}} ]=\check{p} _{1}(t)\) and \(\mathbb{E}[p_{2}(t)|\mathcal{F}_{t}^{2}]=\mathbb{E} [p_{2}(t)|\mathcal{F}_{t}^{S_{1},S_{2}} ]=p_{2}(t)\). Based on Theorem 6.1, we start to solve Problem (F) by three steps.
Step 1: Optimal investment strategy.
The optimal investment strategy of Problem (F) is
where \((y,z_{1},z_{2},p_{1},p_{2})\) is the unique solution of
It is easy to check that the optimal filter \((\check{y},\check{z}_{1}, \check{z}_{2},\check{p}_{1},\check{p}_{2})\) of \((y,z_{1},z_{2},p_{1},p _{2})\) in (62) still satisfies (47), and then y̌ and \(\check{p}_{1}\) are represented by (60) and (56), respectively.
Step 2: Existence and uniqueness of ( 63 ).
The first equation and the third equation of (62) are written as
It follows from Theorem 4.1 that (63) is uniquely solvable.
Step 3: The explicit form of optimal investment strategy.
In order to obtain the feedback optimal investment strategy, we have to establish the relationship between \(p_{2}\) and \(y,\check{y}\). Noticing the first equation of (63) together with the terminal condition in (63), we set
Applying Itô’s formula to \(p_{2}\) in (64), we have
where \(f_{1}\) and \(f_{2}\) are given by (59). Comparing (65) with the second equation of (63), we obtain
Substituting (66) into (67), we obtain
where \(\mathbb{E}y\) is given by (61). (68) implies that
which has a unique solution \((\delta _{1},\delta _{2},\delta _{3})\).
Due to (64), the first equation of (63) is written as
where \(f_{3}(t)=BM_{1}(t)+BM_{2}(t)-\eta _{1}(t)-\delta _{3}(t)-(\gamma _{1}(t)+\delta _{2}(t))\check{y}(t)\). Solving (70), we get its unique solution
where \(\varLambda _{s}=\exp \{\int_{t}^{s} [-r( \omega )+\delta _{1}(\omega )-\frac{1}{2}b_{1}^{2}(\omega )- \frac{1}{2}b_{2}^{2}(\omega ) ]\,d\omega -\int_{t} ^{s} b_{1}(\omega )\,dW_{1}(\omega )- \int_{t}^{s} b_{2}( \omega )\,dW_{2}(\omega ) \}\).
Theorem 6.2
Under Hypotheses 8–9, the optimal investment strategy of Problem (F) is uniquely given by
where \(\gamma _{1}\), \(\eta _{1}\), and y̌ are given by (48) and (60), respectively; \(\delta _{1}, \delta _{2}, \delta _{3}\), and y are given by (69) and (71), respectively.
7 Conclusion and outlook
In this paper, a necessary condition and a sufficient condition for Nash equilibrium point of MF-BSDE under asymmetric information are derived, which are used to solve an MF-LQ problem and a financial problem. Some explicit Nash equilibrium points and optimal investment strategies are obtained. The results obtained here extend the first two authors’ previous works of [12, 14], and [28].
The results in Sects. 5–6 are based on special information structures, which are generated by Brown motion or its components. The case that the information structures are general is not considered. We hope to return to it in a future work. Besides, we assume that all coefficients of the MF-LQ problem and Problem (F) are deterministic. Otherwise, there is an immediate difficulty to solve the problems with stochastic coefficients. We will come back to the problems in the future.
Abbreviations
- MF-BSDE:
-
mean-field backward stochastic differential equation
- MF-LQ:
-
mean-field linear-quadratic
- SDEs:
-
stochastic differential equations
- MF-FBSDE:
-
mean-field forward and backward stochastic differential equation
- ODEs:
-
ordinary differential equations
References
Lasry, J.M., Lions, P.L.: Mean-field games. Jpn. J. Math. 2, 229–260 (2007)
Huang, M., Malhamé, R.P., Caines, P.E.: Large population stochastic dynamic games: closed-loop McKean–Vlasov systems and the Nash certainty equivalence principle. Commun. Inf. Syst. 6(3), 221–252 (2006)
Bensoussan, A., Sung, K.C.J., Yam, S.C.P., Yung, S.P.: Linear-quadratic mean field games. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 169, 496–529 (2016)
Øksendal, B., Sulem, A.: Optimal control of predictive mean-field equations and applications to finance. In: Stochastics of Environmental and Financial Economics. Springer Proceedings in Mathematics and Statistics, vol. 138, pp. 301–320. Springer, Cham (2016)
Wu, J., Liu, Z.: Maximum principle for mean-field zero-sum stochastic differential game with partial information and its application to finance. Eur. J. Control 37, 8–15 (2017)
Hafayed, M., Abbas, S., Abba, A.: On mean-field partial information maximum principle of optimal control for stochastic systems with Lévy processes. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 167, 1051–1069 (2015)
Huang, J., Wang, S.: Dynamic optimization of large-population systems with partial information. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 168, 231–245 (2016)
Pardoux, E., Peng, S.: Adapted solution of a backward stochastic differential equation. Syst. Control Lett. 14, 55–61 (1990)
Shen, X., Jiang, L.: BSDEs with monotone generator driven by time-changed Lévy noises. Adv. Differ. Equ., 2017, 214 (2017)
Mu, R., Wu, Z.: One kind of multiple dimensional Markovian BSDEs with stochastic linear growth generators. Adv. Differ. Equ. 2015, 265 (2015)
Hamadène, S., Lepeltier, J.P.: Zero-sum stochastic differential games and backward equations. Syst. Control Lett. 24, 259–263 (1995)
Wang, G., Yu, Z.: A partial information non-zero sum differential game of backward stochastic differential equations with applications. Automatica 48, 342–352 (2012)
Wang, G., Xiao, H., Xiong, J.: A kind of linear quadratic non-zero sum differential game of backward stochastic differential equation with asymmetric information. Automatica 97, 346–352 (2018)
Wang, G., Yu, Z.: A Pontryagin’s maximum principle for non-zero sum differential games of BSDEs with applications. IEEE Trans. Autom. Control 55(7), 1742–1747 (2010)
Li, N., Yu, Z.: Recursive stochastic linear-quadratic optimal control and nonzero-sum differential game problems with random jumps. Adv. Differ. Equ. 2015, 144 (2015)
Buckdahn, R., Djehiche, B., Li, J., Peng, S.: Mean-field backward stochastic differential equations: a limit approach. Ann. Probab. 37(4), 1524–1565 (2009)
Ma, H., Liu, B.: Infinite horizon optimal control problem of mean-field backward stochastic delay differential equation under partial information. Eur. J. Control 36, 43–50 (2017)
Li, X., Sun, J., Xiong, J.: Linear quadratic optimal control problems for mean-field backward stochastic differential equations. Appl. Math. Optim. (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00245-017-9464-7
Wu, J., Liu, Z.: Maximum principle for mean-field zero-sum stochastic differential game with partial information and its application to finance. Eur. J. Control 37, 8–15 (2017)
Lin, Y., Jiang, X., Zhang, W.: Open-loop Stackelberg strategy for the linear quadratic mean-field stochastic differential game. IEEE Trans. Autom. Control 64(1), 97–110 (2019)
Du, K., Wu, Z.: Linear-quadratic Stackelberg game for mean-field backward stochastic differential system and application. Math. Probl. Eng. (2019). https://doi.org/10.1155/2019/1798585
Zhang, H.: An optimal control problem for linear SDE of mean-field type with terminal constraint and partial information. Adv. Differ. Equ. 2019, 160 (2019)
Peng, S.: Backward stochastic differential equations and applications to optimal control. Appl. Math. Optim. 27, 125–144 (1993)
Yu, Z., Ji, S.: Linear-quadratic nonzero-sum differential game of backward stochastic differential equations. In: Proc. 27th Chinese Control Conf, pp. 562–566 (2008)
Bensoussan, A., Yam, S.C.P., Zhang, Z.: Well-posedness of mean-field type forward-backward stochastic differential equations. Stoch. Process. Appl. 125, 3327–3354 (2015)
Xiong, J.: An Introduction to Stochastic Filtering Theory. Oxford University Press, London (2008)
Wang, G., Wu, Z., Xiong, J.: An Introduction to Optimal Control of FBSDE with Incomplete Information. Springer, Berlin (2018)
Huang, P., Wang, G.: A non-zero sum differential game of mean-field backward stochastic differential equation. In: Proc. 2017 Chinese Automation Congress, pp. 4827–4831 (2017)
Acknowledgements
Not applicable.
Availability of data and materials
Not applicable.
Authors’ information
Not applicable.
Funding
This work is supported in part by the NSF of China under Grants 61821004, 61633015, and 11831010, by the Young Chang Jiang Scholars Program of Chinese Education Ministry, and by the Cultivation Program of Distinguished Young Scholars of Shandong University under Grant 2017JQ06.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Contributions
All authors contributed equally and significantly in writing this article. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.
Corresponding author
Ethics declarations
Competing interests
The authors declare that they have no conflict of interests.
Additional information
Publisher’s Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Rights and permissions
Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.
About this article
Cite this article
Huang, P., Wang, G. & Zhang, H. An asymmetric information non-zero sum differential game of mean-field backward stochastic differential equation with applications. Adv Differ Equ 2019, 236 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1186/s13662-019-2166-5
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s13662-019-2166-5
Keywords
- Mean-field backward stochastic differential equation
- Asymmetric information
- Nash equilibrium point
- Maximum principle
- Filter